ARTICLE CONTENTS

Cost-benefit analysis of financial regulation: case studies and implications.

abstract . Some members of Congress, the D.C. Circuit, and the legal academy are promoting a particular, abstract form of cost-benefit analysis for financial regulation: judicially enforced quantification. How would CBA work in practice, if applied to specific, important, representative rules, and what is the alternative? Detailed case studies of six rules—(1) disclosure rules under Sarbanes-Oxley section 404; (2) the SEC’s mutual fund governance reforms; (3) Basel III’s heightened capital requirements for banks; (4) the Volcker Rule; (5) the SEC’s cross-border swap proposals; and (6) the FSA’s mortgage reforms—show that precise, reliable, quantified CBA remains unfeasible. Quantified CBA of such rules can be no more than “guesstimated,” as it entails (a) causal inferences that are unreliable under standard regulatory conditions; (b) the use of problematic data; and/or (c) the same contestable, assumption-sensitive macroeconomic and/or political modeling used to make monetary policy, which even CBA advocates would exempt from CBA laws. Expert judgment remains an inevitable part of what advocates label “gold-standard” quantified CBA, because finance is central to the economy, is social and political, and is non-stationary. Judicial review of quantified CBA can be expected to do more to camouflage discretionary choices than to discipline agencies or promote democracy.

author. John F. Cogan Jr. Professor of Law and Economics, Harvard Law School. Thanks for helpful discussions—but no blame for the contents of this paper—should go to Stephen An solabehere , John Armour , Michael Barr, Ryan Bubb , John Campbell, Mark Cohen, Clarke Cooper, Jim Cox, Paul Davies, Mihir Desai, Nancy Doyle, Eilis Ferran , Jeff Frieden , Jeff Gordon, Howell Jackson, Robert Jackson, Louis Kaplow , Duncan Kennedy, Andrei Kirilenko , Bruce Kraus, Alex Lee, Craig Lewis, John Manning, Miguel de la Mano, Tom Merrill, Robert Plaze , Eric Posner, Connor Raso , Mark Roe, Paul Rose, Ava Scheibler , Hal Scott, Holger Spamann , Suraj Srinivasan , Matthew Stephenson, Larry Summers, Cass Sunstein , Meg Tahyar , Dan Tarullo , Adrian Vermeule , Chris Walker, Scott Westfahl , Glen Weyl , and Richard Zeckhauser , and to workshop participants at Harvard Law School, Harvard Business School, Columbia Law School, the Securities and Exchange Commission, the Commodity Futures Trading Commission, and the Public Company Accounting Oversight Board. Any errors are mine.

For disclosure of financial interests potentially relevant to this Article, see Faculty Disclosures re: Related Outside Interests and Activities , Harv . L. Sch. , http://www.law.harvard.edu /faculty/COI/2012_Coates_John.html [http://perma.cc/M3VN-8K2P]; and Faculty Disclosures re: Related Outside Interests and Activities , Harv . L. Sch. , http://www.law.harvard.edu/faculty/COI /2013_Coates_John.html [http://perma.cc/TTH6-LNFE].

Introduction

A movement is afoot to impose cost-benefit analysis (CBA) on financial regulation (CBA/FR). 1 The housing and financial crises of 2008 led to the Dodd-Frank Act, 2 which restructured the financial regulatory agencies, mandated more than 200 new rules, and required changes to many older rules. 3 The sweep of regulatory change has reignited criticism for failure to base the changes on adequate CBA/FR. 4 Bills have been introduced to provide explicit authority for the President to require CBA/FR from independent agencies, 5 even as critics argue that existing law already requires the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) to conduct a particular form of CBA/FR: judicially enforced quantification. 6 One panel of the United States Court of Appeals for the District of Columbia Circuit, composed entirely of Republican-appointed judges, held that existing law requires the SEC to quantify the costs and benefits of its proposed rules, 7 while another judge—appointed by President Obama to the D.C. Circuit—subsequently held that such quantification is not mandatory, at least when the SEC is required by statute to adopt a rule, and the benefits sought to be achieved are humanitarian and not economic in nature. 8

This Article critiques efforts to impose judicially reviewed, quantified CBA on independent financial agencies, while also attempting both to explore how conceptual CBA/FR could lead to better policy and to advance the substantive project of quantitative CBA/FR itself. This combination of objectives represents a moderate stance, between the polar positions that often characterize debates over CBA; the Article neither rejects it utterly nor embraces it naively. Rather, the Article explores how CBA is likely to function in the near term as applied to financial regulation and assesses the costs and benefits of using CBA/FR. In other words, the Article begins to develop a CBA of CBA/FR itself. The results of the exploration not only call into question simplistic efforts to mandate CBA—particularly quantified CBA, and particularly when enforced through judicial review by generalist courts—but also should help those who favor economic analysis of law to appreciate how CBA might advance and clarify policy analysis of financial regulation, rather than retard or obscure it.

Part I analyzes CBA generally, noting that it (a) can be either a framework for policy analysis or a legal means to discipline agencies and (b) can consist of either conceptual analysis or efforts at quantification. Part I also briefly reviews CBA’s origins in U.S. legal history to show that it can be used to camouflage as well as to discipline, referring to the Taylor Rule to explain why even CBA’s advocates do not propose to require CBA for monetary policy. Often, CBA is defended in part on the grounds that supposed alternatives—such as expert discretionary judgment—are no better, and often worse, than CBA. In fact, Part I suggests, CBA may turn out not to be an alternative to reliance on judgment: instead, expert judgment is a core and necessary component of CBA, as it is for any process of assessing and adopting financial regulations.

Part II describes existing law relevant to CBA/FR and investigates ongoing efforts to promote quantified CBA/FR. Chief among these efforts has been a string of high-profile CBA cases over the last decade in which courts have struck down financial regulations. Part II critically assesses those cases, showing they have been poorly reasoned, premised on mistakes, inconsistent with precedent, and based on misunderstandings about what CBA/FR can reasonably be expected to do. Nevertheless, those decisions have fueled efforts in the agencies themselves to undertake more CBA/FR. More problematically, those cases have also fueled efforts in Congress to give courts an even more expanded role in enforcing a general mandate for the independent agencies to include quantified CBA in rulemaking.

Part III develops case studies of how quantified CBA/FR might be conducted on six significant and representative financial regulations, drawing on relevant academic research to outline the tasks that need to be tackled to conduct CBA/FR on those rules. The case studies show that quantified CBA/FR amounts to no more than “ guesstimation ,” entailing: (a) causal inferences that are unreliable under standard regulatory conditions; (b) the use of problematic data; and/or (c) the same kinds of contestable, assumption-sensitive macroeconomic or political modeling used to make monetary policy.

Part IV concludes by reviewing the implications of the case studies. Anyone who supports CBA should agree that CBA should be conducted only to the extent it passes its own test—that is, only if CBA itself will produce more benefits than costs. Perhaps surprisingly, given that CBA has been part of administrative law for decades, CBA of CBA has itself never been adequately conducted, leaving the first-stage choice of when to perform CBA/FR itself in the realm of judgment rather than science. Part IV begins the task of outlining a CBA of CBA, both generally and in the context of financial regulation. It argues that the benefits of CBA/FR have been low in the past and are likely to remain low in the near future, while its costs will depend on the precise institutional and legal context in which it is pursued.

CBA/FR’s benefits are likely to remain low because it is by definition about finance: finance is at the heart of the economy; is social and political; and is characterized by non-stationary relationships that exhibit secular change (that is, long-term structural changes). These features undermine the ability of science to precisely and reliably estimate the effects of financial regulations, even retrospectively. Whenever agencies face such sensitive and speculative forecasting abilities, quantified CBA is not capable of disciplining regulatory analysis. It will generate low benefits in the form of reduced agency costs (in part by counteracting cognitive biases) or increased transparency. Moreover, CBA/FR will produce costs: resources consumed, regulatory delay, diffusion of regulatory focus, and potential decreases in regulatory transparency—particularly if regulatory agencies and courts involved in reviewing agency action do not have strong incentives to be honest about the limits of the results.

At the same time, CBA/FR is a useful conceptual framework, and quantified CBA/FR is a worthy long-term research goal. Attempts to quantify may advance the research needed to achieve reliable, precise estimates, and this makes quantified CBA/FR a worthwhile project for agencies to pursue. But the current benefits of CBA/FR remain low, because their real effects remain far off in time; like any regulatory benefits, the benefits of CBA/FR should be discounted to present value.

Completing a full, quantified CBA of CBA would require evidence and new research methods: studies of the degree to which CBA results in better regulations or more transparency in the regulatory process, as well as quantified estimates of the costs—delay, confusion, camouflage, partisanship—that CBA can introduce. Until evidence is developed to illuminate when CBA/FR passes its own test, courts and secondary agencies (that is, agencies other than those charged with rulemaking responsibility) should have no role in second-guessing the choice of when to conduct CBA/FR, or the details of CBA/FR when it is used. 9 Not only should new legal CBA/FR mandates be resisted as likely to worsen policy outcomes, but existing interpretations of the Administrative Procedure Act (APA) and financial agencies’ governing statutes should also be reversed. A safe harbor should be created to shelter the CBA/FR that the agencies choose to conduct, so as to reduce the influence of concentrated interests through litigation and of politically partisan but unaccountable judges on regulatory outcomes. 10 In sum, CBA/FR remains a potentially valuable regulatory tool, but only if implemented with a light touch.

As reflected in Part IV, this Article’s critique of CBA/FR is not sweeping. Rather, it is focused on one specific institutional arrangement for CBA/FR: mandates (whether through new statutes or judicial interpretations of existing statutes) for judicially reviewed, quantified CBA. Other arrangements that include CBA—such as the use of conceptual CBA on a voluntary basis by independent agencies—are much more promising. In between are a wide variety of possible arrangements, such as interagency review of CBA/FR (whether conceptual or quantitative) by a separate agency, as is currently done for rulemakings by executive agencies. Each such arrangement deserves its own fact-specific analysis. For example, for any interagency process, one should ask: How much of the interagency dialogue would become part of the public record, available for use in a subsequent judicial challenge? What real resources could the alternative agency bring to bear on the discussion? Would that other agency face genuinely different incentives in evaluating a given regulation, and how much value would participation by such an agency add if included in pre-rulemaking discussions? How important is it to achieve uniformity on specific kinds of CBA inputs, and alternatively, how important is it to allow for flexibility in such inputs over time and across agencies? As a result of the complexity of these questions, the full range of possible alternative institutional arrangements is not analyzed in detail in this Article. However, some of the reasons offered as to why judicially reviewed quantitative CBA/FR may not satisfy a cost-benefit test may also extend to those other arrangements, and the analysis here should at least illuminate policy debates over those alternatives.

I. what do people mean by “cost-benefit analysis”?

The literature on cost-benefit analysis is voluminous and multi-disciplinary. 11 Not surprisingly, writers often talk past one another when they discuss the topic. Three distinctions are often elided: whether by CBA one means policy analysis or law; whether by CBA one means a conceptual framework or quantification; and whether CBA is likely to camouflage or discipline regulation. 12 In this Part, I begin by presenting a brief typology of CBA and conclude by sketching the alternatives to CBA.

A. Policy Versus Law

Lawyers instinctively understand the difference between a norm or a policy, on the one hand, and a law, on the other—even when that law tracks a norm or policy. They know, for example, that the effects of a law (assumed to be justiciable) requiring an agency to act reasonably will not simply equate to the actions that an agency, acting reasonably, would take. A requirement imposes a set of burdens on the agency that the demands of reason do not. Law introduces new agents into the picture—usually, courts. Those agents are no more perfect than others, and their decisions will be uncertain. Agencies subject to court oversight will anticipate judicial error (or bias).

A law will lead an agency to keep more careful track of what it does, and why, than reason on its own would do. Agencies will incur costs to keep track in this way, just as they will incur costs to defend decisions against court challenges. They will refrain from acting when the expected cost of a challenge and record keeping falls below the expected benefit of the action, discounted for the risk that the court will wrongly overturn the decision. These consequences arise from enforcement and oversight by courts. Law changes behavior even when a law on its face only requires what someone would try to do anyway. 13

Lawyers also know that a law requiring an agency to act reasonably will sound innocuous to most non-lawyers: who could be against acting reasonably? Lawyers know that non-lawyers systematically underestimate enforcement costs and their effects. They know that a clever way to shape regulation is to propose a law that tracks a general norm, the enforcement of which will have predictable effects that are not intuitive to non-lawyers. The asymmetry in perceived effect will allow political gains at a lower political cost than a straightforward law mandating or forbidding regulation.

These themes play themselves out when lawyers discuss CBA with non-lawyers. Specifically, non-lawyers typically mean by CBA the conduct of cost-benefit analysis itself—whether by researchers, regulators, or courts. Lawyers sometimes use CBA in the same way, referring to a particular type of policy analysis. But lawyers also often mean by CBA a set of legal requirements aimed at inducing regulatory agencies to conduct CBA exclusively or as part of their policy analysis in choosing to adopt or change regulations. When lawmakers, for example, describe a proposed law as requiring CBA, many non-lawyers will think of CBA as policy analysis and, if they favor using CBA in policy analysis, will assume that the law is a good idea. They will effectively conflate CBA as policy analysis with CBA as legal requirement. As with a requirement of reasonableness, however, a requirement of CBA will predictably have effects that diverge from those that would arise if CBA were simply used as a routine part of an agency’s policy toolkit, without a legal requirement. 14

B. Quantities (or Guesstimates) Versus Concepts

A second source of confusion arises even within CBA as policy analysis. Most advocates of CBA expect it to include quantification and monetization. This type of cost-benefit analysis—if supported by strong consensus theory, reliable research designs, and good, representative evidence—could properly be called quantifiedCBA , 15 but—if supported only by weak, contested theory, unreliable research designs, or poor, unrepresentative evidence—better deserves the label guesstimated CBA . Robert W. Hahn and co-authors, for example, criticized executive agencies for failing to comply with Executive Orders requiring CBA, 16 based on the authors’ assessment that

agencies only quantified net benefits—the dollar value of expected benefits minus expected costs—for 29 percent of the forty-eight rules [reviewed by the authors], even though the Executive Order directs agencies to show that the benefits of a regulation “justify” the costs. . . . Although agencies may present reasons not to quantify and monetize benefits and costs, . . . we believe they should be able to meet the requirements of the Executive Order for a majority of regulations. 17

Expectations of quantification have found their way into legal decisions overturning financial regulations, as discussed in Part II. For example, in Chamber of Commerce v. SEC , the D.C. Circuit held that the SEC acted arbitrarily and capriciously for failing to undertake some effort to quantify the costs of the mutual fund governance rule changes it had adopted. 18

Others accept—indeed, often make rhetorical show of conceding 19 —that quantification or monetization is not possible in some policy areas but nonetheless believe that CBA can function as a disciplined framework for specifying baselines and alternatives, for ensuring that (at least conceptually) both costs and benefits of a rule are considered, and for encouraging reliance on “evidence” rather than solely on intuitive judgment. 20 These types of CBA are best distinguished from quantified or guesstimated CBA with the label conceptual CBA .

Transforming conceptual CBA into quantified CBA is not an all-or-nothing proposition. Some effects of a given rule might be reliably quantified and monetized, while others might not be. Some inputs to CBA may be quantified, for example, to “scope” the domain of a proposed rule—how many people, transactions, entities, and the like would be covered by the rule. But quantified CBA in its ideal form—which some of its advocates refer to as “complete” quantified CBA 21 —entails specification and quantification of all benefits and costs in a single, uniform bottom-line metric (typically, dollars) representing the net welfare effects of a proposed rule. Some CBA supporters acknowledge that such an idealized version will not be feasible in “some” instances and have conceded that in such instances a more limited CBA—guesstimated CBA—should not determine regulatory outcomes. For example, in a 1996 policy article in Science , Kenneth Arrow and ten other economists advocated CBA but were careful to note that

[ b] enefits and costs of proposed policies should be quantified wherever possible. . . . In most instances, it should be possible to describe the effects of proposed policy changes in quantitative terms; however, not all impacts can be quantified, let alone be given a monetary value. Therefore, care should be taken to assure that quantitative factors do not dominate important qualitative factors in decision-making. 22

Particularly difficult to quantify or monetize are non-market goods and externalities. In non-financial regulatory domains, non-market goods, such as life, health, beauty, and biodiversity, have proven difficult to monetize with any degree of precision and confidence. 23

In financial regulation, relevant non-market goods include trust, investor confidence, liquidity, and the psychological consequences of unexpected financial losses. 24 In non-financial regulation, measurement of externalities has proven difficult, not only because these externalities are often non-market goods, but also because simply specifying and estimating their size is challenging. Financial regulation poses equally if not more difficult problems in measuring externalities, in part because financial markets are tightly interconnected systems (hence the now mainstream phrase “systemic risk”), in which one party’s losses can be rapidly transmitted to multiple related parties. 25 As explained in Part III and discussed further in Part IV, full quantification in CBA/FR is likely to be difficult because finance is at the heart of the economy, involves groups of people (firms, markets) interacting in complex, difficult-to-study ways, and is shaped by forces that change rapidly over time.

Short of full monetization, CBA can include efforts to estimate ranges of costs and benefits, to bound them, to conduct “threshold” analyses comparing a rule’s quantified costs to unquantifiable benefits (or vice versa), and, more generally, to use empirical methods and data to generate evidence relevant to quantified or conceptual CBA. While ranges, bounds, threshold analyses, and incomplete but relevant evidence may all be viewed as part of quantified CBA, they begin to move the final result of CBA toward guesstimation , leaving it a matter of judgment whether and how the results of CBA should influence decision making. For example, guidelines from the Office of Management and Budget (OMB) provide little help in determining how to conduct threshold analyses if important benefits and costs are both unquantifiable, simply suggesting that agencies “exercise professional judgment” in weighing unquantifiable elements in the CBA. 26 This recommendation is hard to criticize. But it also suggests that there may be circumstances in which a feasible but partial quantification will not be cost-justified. For example, it may be the case that the quantifiable elements are likely (based on judgment) to be trivial relative to the unquantifiable elements. It may also be that partial quantification is costly, or otherwise will undermine the value of a conceptual CBA, by—for example—conveying a false degree of precision to a general audience.

One also can draw a distinction within CBA law—analogous to the one between conceptual and quantified CBA—between CBA mandates and CBA process ,although this is not typical in prior CBA scholarship. CBA mandates consist of efforts to require agencies to conduct some or all elements of CBA policy—presumably because legislators believe agencies must be forced to conduct it. CBA mandates include laws subjecting the CBA policy analysis itself to review by another agency (such as the Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA), a unit of OMB ), or by courts (as in review of rules as “arbitrary” and “capricious” under the APA). 27 The objectives of this review are to ensure that the agencies take statutory CBA mandates seriously and (in theory) to improve the quality of CBA analyses. CBA mandates encompass binding executive orders or other interagency guidelines that specify particular components of CBA policy analysis, such as discount rates, or methods to quantify benefits or costs, with the goal of achieving uniformity across governmental agencies. 28 Finally, CBA mandates can be a component of regulation itself—that is, an agency could require a private actor to demonstrate that a new activity or product would have greater benefits than costs before it could be permissibly sold. 29

CBA process, by contrast, includes requirements for agencies to publicly disclose any CBA they conduct, or the sources of their data, and to solicit public comment and feedback on their CBA analyses (as under the APA). 30 CBA process laws can require agencies to discuss how they took comments into account in their final rulemaking decision, to present their CBAs in particular or standardized formats, or to include specific kinds of information, such as standard statistics or data analyses that bear on the reliability of the primary findings of a quantified CBA. Such indicators of reliability include, for example, confidence intervals, p -values, test statistics, correlation matrices, sensitivity analyses, and the results of “Monte Carlo” simulations. Such “soft law” requirements may be viewed as a means of enhancing the quality of the agencies’ decisions by encouraging deliberation and care, or as a means of increasing public understanding and the legitimacy of adopted rules. These process requirements can also have less desirable effects, however, including delay, regulatory inertia, ill-informed judicial second-guessing, creation of incentives for agencies to engage in CBA for show, and waste of regulatory resources.

dimensions of cost-benefit analysis

Putting the first two dimensions of CBA together, Table 1 illustrates the multiple meanings that apparently synonymous uses of “cost-benefit analysis” might have for different speakers or audiences. Table 1 suggests that it is possible to be an advocate for CBA/FR—whether conceptual or quantified—as a form of policy analysis without wanting to entangle it in the legal system; or that it is possible to favor efforts to quantify CBA/FR without wanting to mandate quantification. One might even be skeptical that CBA/FR law will have any effect at all. 31 Alternatively, if CBA/FR has clear virtues as policy analysis, one might believe that those virtues would lead agencies to use it, at least sometimes, without being legally required to do so, just as private businesses adopt “best practices” on a voluntary basis. Likewise, one can favor CBA/FR process laws without agreeing that courts or any other agency should have any substantive role in evaluating or constraining the content of CBA/FR. Or one could imagine mandating that a second political agent (a specialized court or another agency) conduct the CBA/FR analysis itself; the analysis would then have to be used by the primary agencies as inputs into their rulemaking decisions, without necessarily adding other process requirements to CBA/FR law.

C. Camouflage Versus Discipline

A third dimension along which CBA can vary is the motive of the person using it—and, relatedly, its effects on third parties. The conventional, optimistic view of CBA advocates—generally assumed or asserted rather than supported with evidence 32 —is that CBA is an agency cost-control device, used by politically accountable representatives (Congress or the President) to discipline expert but less accountable agencies (made up of appointed bureaucrats) in their rulemaking efforts. In this view, CBA will improve the care that agencies exercise in deciding whether a possible rule change is good for society while limiting agencies’ ability to adopt welfare-reducing rules. 33 CBA optimists tend to assume or assert that CBA will enhance public understanding of why regulations are adopted (increase transparency ) 34 and engage more people in the democratic process, potentially combating pernicious rent seeking by special interests. 35 By specifying how a rule will produce benefits, by acknowledging the costs involved, and by encouraging the consideration of alternatives, CBA is expected to improve the allocation of governmental resources and reduce the drag of regulation on beneficial activities. 36 Some but not all CBA optimists even assert that CBA can mitigate cognitive biases of regulators or the public. 37

Despite having potential virtues, however, CBA can have a different, darker, or more complex mix of effects. It can provide camouflage, reducing the transparency of a rulemaking process. 38 More disclosure does not always improve transparency, a point that (ironically) some CBA advocates have made strenuously when resisting disclosure rules for private actors. 39 Beyond the indeterminate effects of CBA soft law on the ability of the public to monitor regulatory agencies, CBA can also be a tool of political struggle over the distribution of rents, and it can serve as a means to increase the power of unelected expert agents as a tactic in that struggle. 40

The origins of CBA in the United States illustrate this set of possibilities. It is commonly asserted that Congress “initiated the use of CBA in 1936, when [it] ordered agencies to weigh the costs and benefits of projects designed for flood control,” 41 permitting authorization of such projects only if “the benefits to whomsoever they accrue are in excess of the estimated costs.” 42 This origin story fits the optimistic view of CBA outlined above, making it a mechanism used by elected and accountable representatives to control costs at a wayward agency. In fact, however, the use of CBA by the Army Corps of Engineers emerged earlier, on the initiative of the Corps itself, as described in Theodore M. Porter’s Trust in Numbers . 43 In Porter’s telling, the first efforts at CBA occurred in 1902, with the creation of a board within the Corps; opponents of public works spending hoped that the board’s performance of cost-benefit analysis and its issuance of recommendations would “reduce opportunities for purely political choices.” 44 Rather than ranking all projects based on CBA, which would have systematized project choice, the Corps chose to maintain flexibility, “recognizing, it seems, that congressional choice was the key to congressional favor.” 45 Far from being a tool for the management of the Corps, CBA became a tool by some politicians and by the Corps to manipulate Congress.

The Corps had developed a “huge civilian labor force” prior to the 1936 Flood Control Act, which mandated strict CBA for new projects. That Act, too, Porter concludes, was not aimed at disciplining the Corps, but was “one of the heroic efforts of the United States Congress to control its own bad habits.” 46 The Act’s requirements, and particularly the delay requirement, were viewed as a benefit, and not a necessary cost, of conducting CBA: “A preliminary examination and then a full survey, each running through several levels of Corps bureaucracy, required months or years, and could not be completed to satisfy the sudden whim of a legislator.” 47 Far from reducing the power of the Corps, the regularization of the project approval process (and the implementation of CBA) enhanced it, because neither Congress nor the public exerted the effort needed to evaluate and assess the Corps’s numerically impressive but sometimes ad hoc analyses: “The numbers were almost never questioned.” 48

If some members of Congress favored a particular outcome, they could attempt to “manage” the Corps by finding unorthodox benefits to “quantify” (or include in a guesstimated CBA). One local district’s engineer, faced with an unfavorable CBA report based solely on flood control benefits, “developed other benefits that he did not find . . . necessary to develop when he wrote his main report,” including benefits from downstream power, pollution abatement, and improved water supply. 49 Over time, more benefits were guesstimated, and previously rejected projects were accepted. 50 The result, in Porter’s view, was that “Corps economic methods [that is, its CBA] could not, by themselves, determine the outcome of an investigation.” 51 This observation was particularly true when powerful interest groups, such as the utility and railroad industries, or other regulatory bodies, such as units of the Department of Agriculture or the Interior Department, opposed the Corps’s initial conclusions. 52

In sum, CBA can in principle provide public-regarding benefits by disciplining agencies, increasing transparency, and enhancing the public’s engagement with the regulatory process. In theory, CBA can reduce agency costs associated with delegation by politically accountable lawmakers to expert but less accountable agencies. But CBA can have other effects beyond direct costs of the CBA itself. These effects include use of technically opaque analytics to (1) obscure the issues at play, (2) raise the risks for lawmakers to question regulators, (3) shift power from Congress to regulators, (4) hide rent seeking, and (5) favor factions in distributional struggles among lawmakers. One form of camouflage that seems likely to recur is the presentation of guesstimated CBA as quantified CBA—which potentially misleads the public by omitting significant information about the uncertainty, judgment, and sensitivity of particular numerical results in a CBA.

Depending on one’s assumptions about the alignment of agency interests with public interests, these effects may be costly or beneficial. But they should be kept in mind when evaluating a given type of CBA in a given context, and they suggest that CBA itself needs to be subject to CBA before being mandated through law. In Part IV, I sketch a third set of effects that CBA policy can have—stimulating innovation and inducing better regulation over time—that differs from both the disciplinary role touted by advocates of CBA law and the camouflaging role illustrated by the Corps’s history.

D. Alternatives to Quantified CBA/FR

CBA is sometimes promoted on the ground that there is no superior alternative. 53 Leading proponents of CBA/FR in the United Kingdom, for example, acknowledge problems with CBA/FR and then argue these problems do “not . . . mean that the best course would be to fail altogether to deploy the techniques of economic analysis.” 54 (One would hope not!) Yet viable alternatives exist.

In non-financial areas of regulation, agencies use feasibility analysis, which focuses on the technical capacity of private actors to comply with a proposed rule; this procedure pays some attention to costs rather than attempting to quantify the rule’s full range of costs and benefits. 55 Another alternative is risk-risk analysis, in which the risk addressed by a rule is compared to risks that can be expected to arise as private actors respond to the rule. 56 Another option (sometimes included as a component of CBA) is cost-effectiveness analysis, in which costs of different methods of achieving stipulated or assumed benefits are estimated and compared. 57 Yet another, reflected in some important statutes relevant to financial regulation, 58 is a flat ban on certain kinds of activities—that is, requirements that agencies enact and enforce mandatory rules regardless of what an agency’s CBA/FR might suggest about those rules’ net benefits. 59

1. The “Alternative” of Expert Judgment

But the primary “alternative” to guesstimated CBA/FR is expert judgment, which typically includes at least some elements of conceptual CBA (whether or not expressed in writing) and can be elicited and deployed in a variety of ways. More precisely, however, expert judgment is not an “alternative,” but a necessary component of guesstimated or quantified CBA, as the Office of Management and Budget’s guidance on CBA (OMB Guidance) makes clear. 60 When defenders of CBA argue that expert judgment may be—as it often is—flawed, they are also necessarily arguing that CBA is flawed. The question is not, then, “What is the alternative?” Rather, it is, “Is judgment being camouflaged as something it is not?” An honest acceptance of the central role of judgment in policymaking, whether or not decorated with guesstimated CBA, should lower the stakes in the fight over CBA law.

In the context of financial regulation, the judgment of regulatory staff is expert because the appointees of the financial agencies have generally spent their careers in and have developed specialized knowledge of finance, financial institutions, and financial markets. 61 They have sharpened their intuitive sense of what kinds of regulations work and why—particularly relative to non-experts, such as generalist judges. Such intuitions can be disciplined and informed in ways other than through formal CBA, such as through discussions with other experts (within or outside an agency); case studies, surveys, and polls; retrospective evaluations; regulatory experiments that are deliberately adopted without specific predictions about how they will turn out; and other forms of assessment that are not part of quantified CBA/FR. 62

The experience and expertise of financial regulators does not make them infallible: the 2008 financial crisis proves that regulators with expertise can lack judgment, particularly when the challenges they face are novel, as with shadow banking, over-the-counter derivatives, and (ironically) the complex and unanticipated effects of deregulation. 63 More generally, in many domains, experts are no more capable of predicting certain kinds of complex events than non-experts. 64 Nevertheless, in the realm of financial regulation, expert judgment has always played a central role in the setting of monetary policy. This brings us to the Taylor Rule.

2. Monetary Policy: A Limiting Example

To set the stage for case studies of rules in Part III, this section recognizes that even CBA/FR’s proponents do not advocate requiring CBA/FR for monetary policy. 65 As will be seen, guesstimated CBA/FR of monetary policy would result in conceptual, theoretical, and empirical challenges identical to those that arise in the case studies reviewed in Part III. This fact raises the question of why, precisely, CBA/FR proponents believe a line should be drawn between rules for monetary policy and other financial regulations.

To think through how CBA/FR might in principle be applied to monetary policy, consider the Taylor Rule. That “rule” is a principle of monetary policy that stipulates how much the Federal Reserve (or any central bank) should change nominal interest rates in response to changes in prices, output, or other economic quantities. In particular, the Rule stipulates that for a percent increase in inflation, a central bank should raise interest rates by more than a percentage point. 66 First proposed in its specifics by John Taylor in 1993, the Rule sought to reduce uncertainty, limit adaptive inefficiency, and increase credibility by avoiding frequent changes in monetary policy as a result of the exercise of discretion. 67 The Federal Reserve, it should be emphasized, has never “promulgated” the Taylor Rule, nor has it adopted the Rule in any formal or public fashion. 68 Nevertheless, the Rule does fairly characterize (as a first approximation) the monetary policy of the Federal Reserve for some of the years under Chairman Alan Greenspan. 69

Suppose, counterfactually, a future Federal Reserve (or Congress) wanted to “adopt” the Taylor Rule—or any other rule for conducting monetary policy—in a formal fashion. Could the Rule be defended through CBA/FR? Only a few CBA/FR proponents suggest that it could, or should, be defended through CBA. 70 The numerous proposed bills in Congress that would extend CBA to the independent agencies have all exempted monetary policy. 71

Why is monetary policy exempt? Politics and political power play a role, of course: few politicians want to take on the Federal Reserve (even if a few have done so, particularly during the public outcry over the 2008 crisis). 72 History and tradition also play a role: monetary policy in the United States has long been (by consensus) an exercise in discretionary judgment, and it involves balancing multiple goals—full employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates. 73 Any strict rule to set monetary policy according to a full quantified CBA would have to reverse this tradition and implicitly choose a priority scheme for the goals; as a result, the rule would be (to return to politics) highly unlikely to achieve the supermajority support necessary to enact major legislation in the United States.

But policy, too, plays a role here. In a context of high empirical and theoretical uncertainty, multiple competing macroeconomic models have long coexisted to guide the achievement of monetary policy’s goals. However, these models are widely conceded to be contestable, 74 and no one model has ever achieved anything close to a consensus among “mainstream” economists. For this reason, presumably, even the most rule-oriented members of the Federal Reserve have never seriously attempted to persuade the Board to tie its own hands by articulating publicly a “rule” that would eliminate the Board’s discretion to set interest rates.

Absent such hand-tying , there is no need to exempt monetary policy from the proposed CBA/FR laws. So why have they been exempted? Presumably because CBA/FR proponents recognize that there may be welfare-enhancing “rules” (in the sense of regularities in the exercise of discretion that might come within the legal definition of “rule” used in the APA) 75 that can discipline regulators but cannot be reliably shown to satisfy a cost-benefit test. The idea that a “rule” in the general legal sense of the APA could be valuable without being first validated by quantified CBA/FR prevails across many domains of discretionary decision making: in an attempt to constrain itself, a corporate board of directors may decide to adopt rules about the situations in which it wants officers to present an investment to the board (instead of pursuing the investment on their own), but such self-imposed rules may not be defensible under any kind of quantitative framework. Rules, in other words, can be a part of the way that discretionary judgment is exercised. Rules can have value even if they cannot be supported by evidence showing that their quantifiable benefits exceed their quantifiable costs.

Indeed, CBA/FR’s strongest proponents concede that expert judgment is necessary because CBA/FR can only be as good as the expert judgment that informs it. 76 Pro-CBA/FR bills pending in Congress exempt monetary policy, presumably for this reason, and there is no serious call for hard-wiring monetary decisions into legislation or regulation. While there are economists who believe that basing monetary policy on simpler rule-like elements may be a good idea, even they suggest that rule-like monetary policy be adopted as a matter of expert discretion by the Federal Reserve Board and be subject to discretionary exceptions. 77

The question remaining, then, is whether discretionary judgment should be confined to monetary policy or whether it should remain available for financial regulation more broadly. Put differently, the question is whether quantified CBA/FR is itself actually an alternative to judgment, or whether it should be viewed as judgment camouflaged by numbers (“judgment in drag,” one might say, or less colorfully, “judgment in disguise”). To answer that question, a detailed analysis of what CBA/FR might look like is needed.

II. a critical assessment of judicial review of cba/fr

As noted at the outset, a movement is afoot to impose CBA/FR on financial regulation. This movement is flowing through a variety of channels. Interest groups and advocacy organizations have been promoting CBA/FR as both policy and law, and regulators themselves have been beefing up their quantitatively trained staffs. But one big force (perhaps the biggest) that is promoting the role of CBA/FR has been judicial activism—aggressive review of agency decisions by courts focused in large part on CBA. After reviewing statutes relevant to CBA/FR, this Part critically assesses recent cases in the D.C. Circuit that have overturned financial regulations in whole or in part because of what some judges have seen as inadequately quantified CBA/FR. This Part concludes with a summary of how this judicial activism has led some of the financial agencies to engage in more CBA/FR, and has amplified legislative efforts to promote CBA/FR through oversight and proposed legislation.

A. Existing CBA/FR Law

Formally, independent agencies 78 such as the financial regulators are not subject to explicit CBA/FR law to the same extent as executive agencies, which have been required (by executive order since 1981 and by statute since 1995) to conduct CBA for new rules. 79 Vice President George H.W. Bush requested in 1981 that the executive agencies comply with the CBA portions of the executive orders, and some of the financial agencies have at times voluntarily, if incompletely and inconsistently, done so. 80 By contrast, in the United Kingdom, the two main financial regulatory agencies are required by statute to conduct quantified CBA/FR, unless in the opinion of the agencies the costs or benefits “cannot reasonably be estimated” or “it is not reasonably practicable to produce an estimate,” in which case the agency must publish its opinion and explain it. 81

Three CBA-related statutes cover the independent agencies. The Paperwork Reduction Act (PRA) requires agencies to justify collection of information from the public, to minimize the burden of any information collection process, and to maximize the utility of information gathered. 82 The Regulatory Flexibility Act (RFA) requires agencies to assess and consider alternatives to the burden of regulation on small entities. 83 The Congressional Review Act (CRA) requires agencies to submit proposed rules—along with any CBA the agencies have conducted—to Congress and the Government Accountability Office (GAO). 84 The statute requires the GAO to submit an assessment to Congress of any “major rule,” defined as any rule having an expected impact of $100 million or more. 85

As a result of these statutes, independent agencies include some CBA-relevant information in rulemakings, the GAO has been submitting annual reports on CBA for major rules (including rulemakings by independent agencies), and the OMB has collected and reported on the GAO’s reports on an annual basis. 86 Analyses under the PRA and the RFA represent only a subset of a full CBA—even of a full conceptual CBA—and the information in these reports is thin—generally indicating whether CBA was conducted, without regard to whether it was conceptual or quantified, extensive or brief, persuasive or perfunctory. Still, the PRA and RFA have generated information used to critique financial rules on CBA-related grounds, and the GAO’s and OMB’s reports have made the complete absence of voluntary CBA in many rulemakings by independent agencies more salient over time. Together, this information has fueled legislative, inter- and intra-agency, and interest group pressure on the financial regulatory agencies to do more on their own to conduct CBA, and has also led to a sharp increase in industry-funded court challenges to agency rulemakings on CBA/FR grounds.

B. A Critical Assessment of Judicial Review of CBA/FR

Despite the fact that CBA/FR is not clearly required of independent agencies, business trade groups have since 2000 invested significant time and resources to persuade court­­s—primarily the D.C. Circuit—to strike down a series of rules under the APA and under statutes that authorize financial regulation. Cited in internal CBA/FR guidance promulgated by the CFTC and the SEC, these decisions have clouded implementation of the Dodd-Frank Act, contributing significantly to the rulemaking delays under that law. These decisions have had an impact on the legislative process, as lawmakers, lobbyists, and the agencies themselves have noticed that rules receive different treatment depending on whether Congress has required the agencies to enact them or has given the agencies discretion and authority to act on their own.

The first in the recent string of judicial interventions was Chamber of Commerce v. SEC . 87 In that decision, the D.C. Circuit held that the SEC failed to comply with the Investment Company Act (ICA). The ICA requires the SEC to “consider . . . whether [regulatory] action will promote efficiency, competition, and capital formation,” 88 a requirement added to the SEC’s statutory mandates in 1996. 89 As a result, according to the court, the SEC had also violated the APA. 90 The rules in question—discussed in Part III.B—made exemptions under other rules conditional on mutual funds increasing their boards’ independence.

The specific CBA/FR-related failings to which the court pointed were two small parts of the SEC’s regulatory analysis. The first was that the SEC declined to quantify costs of requiring more independent directors because it did not know how funds would respond to the rule. 91 This, the court replied, was no excuse, saying that the SEC could have determined “the range within which a fund’s cost of compliance [would] fall, depending on how it responds to the condition.” 92 Presumably the court had in mind that the SEC could quantify costs of each possible response and guesstimate a range based on assumptions about how many funds would choose each option.

The second failing was similar, relating to a requirement that fund boards have an independent chair. There, the SEC declined to quantify costs of the newly independent chairs’ hiring staff because staffing would be discretionary and the SEC had no basis for knowing how many chairs would hire staff (or how many staff each chair would hire). Again, the court held the SEC needed to guesstimate this subset of costs by estimating the costs for an individual fund, an exercise that the court asserted (without further explanation) would be “pertinent” to an “assessment” of the requirement. 93 But the only way that an individual fund cost estimate would be “pertinent” is if the SEC implicitly or explicitly made further assumptions about how many funds would incur those costs—even though the SEC explicitly noted that it had no reliable basis on which to build the assumptions, and the court offered no reason to doubt the SEC’s claim. 94 The court’s analysis under the APA was nonexistent: because the SEC had not followed the ICA, the court reasoned, it had violated the APA. 95

In sum, the court interpreted the requirement that the SEC “consider” a rule’s effects on “efficiency” to imply a very specific CBA/FR mandate—calling on the SEC to guesstimate the range of one of a rule’s costs, rather than merely identifying the type of cost imposed. The court’s interpretation of the ICA was based on no prior court decision 96 and no legislative history. Nor is it implicit in the ICA’s words, as “efficiency” is frequently used as a qualitative and not exclusively quantitative concept. 97 Nowhere did the court cite (much less discuss) Supreme Court precedent under the APA that had emphasized that courts should be highly deferential in reviewing an agency’s judgment under the “arbitrary and capricious” standard. 98 Nor did it address precedents more generally admonishing courts to be mindful of the “complex nature of economic analysis” in deferring to agencies. 99

Finally, the court never explained how a crude guesstimate of one conditional component of possible costs of a rule could meaningfully inform the public about the “efficiency” of the rule when the SEC had not quantified the benefits of the rule—and when the court did not suggest that the SEC try to do so, whether it could, or how it could if it tried. In other words, the court read general language in the ICA as if it required the SEC to comply with the Executive Orders requiring CBA/FR “to the extent feasible,” 100 and then added an interpretive gloss on OMB Guidance that has little apparent virtue in improving public understanding of the rule. Whatever the merits of the SEC’s mutual fund rules—and there are reasons (noted in Part III.B) to suggest that the rules might not be a good idea on balance—the merits of the court’s decision evaluating the SEC’s rulemaking under the ICA and the APA are hardly compelling and do not appear to reflect any meaningful deference to SEC judgment on how to conduct CBA/FR.

Yet this decision was only the first of a rash of judicial interventions into the financial regulatory process, each opinion growing steadily less deferential, culminating in the 2011 case Business Roundtable v. SEC . 101 In the seven years after Chamber of Commerce , the D.C. Circuit handed down six more similar decisions, striking down a range of SEC actions (representing one in seven of the SEC’s major rules over that period). 102 The D.C. Circuit has struck down a rule requiring registration of hedge fund advisors under the Investment Advisors Act, 103 a rule exempting broker-dealers from registration under that Act, 104 an order affirming expulsion of an NASD-member firm, 105 and a rule treating a new class of securities market-linked annuities as securities. 106 The court also struck down the same mutual fund governance rules from Chamber of Commerce a second time: the SEC, with perhaps tactless speed, patched the guesstimated CBA/FR holes in its rulemaking analysis, only to have its rule struck down on new grounds. 107 Since Chamber of Commerce , only one decision, National Ass’n of Manufacturers v. SEC , has upheld an SEC regulation. 108 Another upheld a CFTC regulation, 109 and another upheld a decision of the Office of Thrift Supervision against CBA/FR-related challenges. 110

Three facts are worth noting about these decisions. First, a business or trade group initiated and funded each of the cases; so far, consumer and investor lobbies have been sitting out these court battles. 111 One-sided use of litigation as a lobbying tactic is not typically a stable feature of enduring battles between interest groups over important regulations. Second, not all of the decisions strike down new regulations—one struck down a new exemption from a regulation, and one overturned an enforcement action. Together, these two facts should give pause to political entrepreneurs who seek to use CBA/FR as a way to attack regulation generally; these observations suggest that CBA/FR law can slow or stop de regulation as easily as it can slow or stop new regulation, particularly if consumer or investor advocates develop and fund their own CBA/FR litigation agendas. Third, each regulatory action (except the action involved in National Ass’n of Manufacturers ) was taken pursuant to the SEC’s general statutory authority to use discretion to adopt regulations in support of the securities laws—and not pursuant to a mandate from Congress to do so. That the District Court in National Ass’n of Manufacturers 112 distinguished the string of anti-SEC precedents on the ground that the Dodd-Frank Act mandated the rule in question reinforces this take-away. Under the current CBA/FR legal regime, regulatory agencies are well advised to seek statutory language that requires them to adopt rules or to enforce rule-like legal requirements via enforcement proceedings that are generally exempt from judicial review under the APA; 113 it is inadvisable to seek language that promotes SEC discretion and authority in rulemaking based on the agency’s expertise. Judicial efforts to promote CBA/FR, in other words, have given expert agencies an incentive to ask an inexpert Congress to tie their hands with inflexible statutory commands.

The most notorious 114 decision in this line of cases was Business Roundtable , which struck down an SEC rule requiring public companies to include in their annual proxy statements, under limited circumstances, 115 information about (and the power to vote for) board nominees nominated by large shareholders rather than solely those nominated by the incumbent board. 116 Despite the SEC’s having debated the issue for over a decade, having developed an extensive public record before adopting the rule, and having adopted the rule under the explicit authority and implicit direction of Congress in section 971 of the Dodd-Frank Act, a panel of the D.C. Circuit struck the rule down as “arbitrary and capricious.” 117 According to the court, the twenty-five single-spaced pages devoted to cost-benefit and related analyses in the adopting release was inadequate under the APA and “failed . . . adequately to assess the economic effects of a new rule.” 118 The D.C. Circuit presented no evidence that there is any available scientific technique for the SEC to “assess the economic effects” of the rule along the lines that the court seemed to think legally required—as when the court held that the SEC “relied upon insufficient empirical data when it concluded that Rule 14a-11 [would] improve board performance and increase shareholder value by facilitating the election of dissident shareholder nominees,” 119 or when it held that the SEC had “arbitrarily ignored the effect of the final rule” because the SEC “does not address whether and to what extent Rule 14a-11 will take the place of traditional proxy contests.” 120

Instead, as in Chamber of Commerce , the U.S. court with “[ s] tatus [s] econd [o] nly to [the] Supreme Court” 121 ignored precedents establishing a “deferential” standard of review under the APA and substituted its own judgment for that of the SEC in evaluating the existing research relevant to proxy contests. In Business Roundtable , the D.C. Circuit went so far as to characterize (without explanation) a peer-reviewed article published in the Journal of Financial Economics as “relatively unpersuasive.” 122 Even the Chamber of Commerce decision had not gone so far, for while that decision invented an obligation for the SEC to use guesstimated CBA/FR on the cost side of its rulemaking, it also held that the SEC need only “determine as best it can the economic implications” of a rule; 123 moreover, Chamber of Commerce nowhere suggested the SEC had to remain inert whenever quantified CBA/FR was simply unavailable. Hypocritically, it was Judge Ginsburg who penned the Business Roundtable decision, just two years after he joined the decision in Stilwell , where the same court held that the APA “imposes no general obligation on agencies to produce empirical evidence .” 124

In sum, the D.C. Circuit’s new interpretations of the APA and statutes authorizing financial regulation have permitted panels to overturn regulatory changes on the ground that a court would conduct its guesstimated CBA differently than an agency would. Since guesstimated CBA/FR is unreliable and imprecise, no matter who conducts it, courts have no legitimate role to second-guess the agencies—even if the agencies are arbitrary in how they go about the guesstimated CBA/FR. Indeed, the state of CBA/FR is such that one can reasonably argue that all guesstimated CBA/FR of major financial regulations inevitably contains multiple arbitrary assumptions and judgments simply to allow for rough guesstimates to be made. Worse, the judges reviewing these guesstimates are political appointees tenured for life, and so—while often selected for political reasons—are immune from conventional forces of political accountability; nonetheless, they have been frequently partisan in their approach to CBA. Because the D.C. Circuit is roughly evenly split between Republican and Democratic appointees, 125 the partisan-driven outcomes in CBA/FR cases are unpredictable and depend on a factor (which judges are chosen for a given case) that has nothing to do with the APA or any other law. The normative implications of this state of affairs are taken up in Part IV.

C. Congressional Oversight, Regulatory Initiatives, and Proposed Legislation

Elements of the legislative branch, as well as the financial agencies’ own initiatives, have reinforced the effect of judicial review of existing CBA-related mandates on the financial agencies’ organic statutes. While Congress has not mandated CBA for independent agencies, members of Congress, in coordination with minority commissioners of the CFTC and the SEC, have pressured the agencies to engage in CBA, both by attempting to pass legislation (discussed below) and with soft power, through hearings, information requests, and public criticism. In 1998, the GAO released a critique of current law for failing to improve CBA in agency rulemakings. 126 As discussed in Part III.B, Fidelity Management in 2004 persuaded Congress to require the SEC to justify proposed rules by preparing a report on their potential benefits. 127 In 2007, the House held hearings on the Sarbanes-Oxley Act, in which one witness (inaccurately) critiqued the SEC’s CBA/FR, 128 a criticism echoed by members of Congress 129 and, more recently, by Republican SEC Commissioner Daniel M. Gallagher. 130

These pressures, along with the court decisions discussed above, have led financial agencies to conduct and publish more CBA/FR in recent years. OMB reports show that this increase in the use of CBA/FR began in the early 2000s. In September 2010, the CFTC’s General Counsel and Acting Chief Economist distributed a memo to the CFTC’s rulemaking teams noting that, while the CFTC’s authorizing statute does not require quantified CBA/FR, it does require the CFTC to consider costs and benefits, and that recent court decisions had been expanding the demands of CBA/FR law under the APA. 131 As a result, the memo directed staff to provide summary CBA/FR in proposed rulemakings and to address conceptual CBA/FR in adopting releases. 132

Despite these efforts, congressional pressures have only increased, potentially stimulated by the financial industry lobbies seeking to influence rulemaking under the Dodd-Frank Act. In 2013, Senator Mike Crapo (Republican of Idaho) pressed the heads of the major financial agencies to commit to “act on GAO’s recommendation to incorporate OMB’s guidance on [CBA] into your proposed and final rules [and] interpretive guidance.” 133 Shortly thereafter, ten Senate Banking Committee members requested financial agency inspector generals to report on CBA under the Dodd-Frank Act, “in response to concerns raised by Commissioners at both the CFTC and the SEC” regarding economic analysis at the agencies. 134 Also in 2011, Congress amended the Dodd-Frank Act to require the GAO to analyze the impact of regulations on the marketplace, 135 and in November 2011, the GAO released a report on the financial agencies’ Dodd-Frank Act rulemakings, finding that “[ a] lthough most of the federal financial regulators told us that they tried to follow [OMB guidance] in principle or spirit, their policies and procedures did not fully reflect OMB guidance on regulatory analysis.” 136 While noting that “for 7 of . . . 10 regulations we reviewed, the agencies generally assessed benefits and costs of the alternative chosen,” 137 the GAO was particularly critical of the financial agencies for not conducting quantified CBA/FR: “[ O]ne of the seven benefit-cost analyses monetized the costs of the regulation, but the analysis did not monetize the benefits. None of the other analyses monetized either the benefits or costs, identified the type and timing of them, or expressed them in constant dollars.” 138 Trade groups and political entrepreneurs have picked up these criticisms, 139 as have members of Congress. 140

In March 2012, SEC staff distributed its own internal CBA/FR guidance. The guidance cited “[ r] ecent court decisions, reports of the [GAO] and the SEC’s . . . [OIG], and Congressional inquiries” that had “raised questions about . . . the [SEC’s] economic analysis in its rulemaking.” 141 The SEC guidance noted “[ n]o statute expressly requires” the SEC to “conduct a formal” CBA but that “SEC chairmen ha[d] informed Congress since at least the early 1980s—and as rulemaking releases since that time reflect—the [SEC] considers potential costs and benefits as a matter of good regulatory practice whenever it adopts rules.” 142 The SEC guidance went on to set out “[ s] ubstantive requirements” for CBA/FR, drawing on the CBA Executive Orders and the OMB Guidance. 143 Rulemaking staff were directed to work with economists on the SEC’s staff to analyze which costs and benefits a rule might create, to quantify those that could be quantified, and to explain why others could not feasibly be quantified.

The bluntest form of congressional pressure has taken the form of bills that would mandate CBA/FR across the board. In June 2013, three Senators reintroduced the Independent Agency Regulatory Analysis Act. 144 That bill would permit the President to order all independent agencies, including all of the financial regulatory agencies, to (among other things) conduct a CBA of any new “rule and, recognizing some costs and benefits are difficult to quantify, propose or adopt a rule only upon a reasoned determination that the benefits of the rule justify its costs.” 145 The bill incorporates the definition of “rule” from the APA and excepts only rules of the Federal Reserve “relating to monetary policy.” 146

In addition, for any “economically significant rule” (ESR), an independent agency could be required to give OIRA and to publicly disclose (1) “an assessment, including the underlying analysis, of benefits . . . [and] costs . . . anticipated . . . with, to the extent feasible, a quantification of those benefits . . . [and] costs,” (2) a similar assessment of all “potentially effective and reasonably feasible alternatives to the rule, identified by the agencies or the public,” and (3) a statement of why the rule is superior to alternatives. 147 For this purpose, the bill defines an ESR as a rule with an annual effect on the economy of $100 million or more. Independent agencies could be required to submit any ESR for a ninety-day OIRA review of whether the rule “has complied” with these requirements, with the OIRA review also to be part of the published record for the rule. Independent agencies would also be required to publish a finding that the rule did comply with the bill, with an explanation of that finding, or “if applicable, an explanation why the independent regulatory agency did not comply.” 148

The bill states that “compliance” by an independent agency with the bill is not subject to judicial review. However, it also states that in any court challenge to an independent agency’s rule under other laws, such as the APA, all material produced by the independent agency and OIRA under this bill would be “part of the whole record” for the court to review. 149 As discussed more in Part IV, mandating an open interagency process formally not subject to judicial review might seem innocuous: how could it impede rulemaking for an independent agency to simply get the input of another agency? But this naïve reading misses the fact that any public interagency process will create a larger record that will be used by litigators to attack particular agency judgments as arbitrary and capricious under the APA: any disagreement between the agencies, for example, will provide grist for the litigation mill. The cases reviewed in this Part show how aggressive some D.C. Circuit panels have been in overturning agency actions on CBA grounds, particularly when an agency’s commissioners have been divided over judgments needed for any regulatory change. Trebling the number of pages or components of a CBA available for judicial second-guessing, and adding the possibility of interagency disagreement to the mix, will almost certainly incite more judicial interventions. 150 Before we can assess whether such interventions might be net beneficial, however, we need to consider CBA/FR itself. Could it offer precise, reliable estimates of the costs and benefits of financial regulation?

III. how might cba of financial regulation work?

In this Part, I outline how the kind of quantified CBA/FR envisioned by its proponents might work in practice. The goals of this Part are to illuminate what we might expect of CBA/FR policy, to advance the substantive research project of developing CBA/FR, and to provide a better empirical basis for evaluating CBA/FR law in Part IV.

To accomplish these goals, I outline the CBA/FR that was performed for four specific rules: (1) SEC regulations under Sarbanes-Oxley Act section 404 (SOX 404); (2) the SEC’s 2002 mutual fund governance proposals; (3) Basel III’s enhanced capital requirements for banks; and (4) the Volcker Rule. These analyses are followed by a review of two rules that have been subject to CBA/FR and have been held up as the “gold standard” by CBA advocates: (5) the SEC’s cross-border swap rules and (6) the UK/FSA’s mortgage market rules.

The first, third, and fourth case studies represent the kind of significant rulemakings that CBA/FR proponents agree should be the focus of CBA/FR, 151 and because they are clearly “economically significant rules,” they would trigger the highest degree of interagency review under the CBA Executive Orders and OMB Guidance if the independent agencies were brought under those process requirements. The second case study focuses on rules that led to the D.C. Circuit decisions reviewed above and stimulated the SEC’s Chief Economist to publish two extensive CBA/FR-related memos that provide one of the better (if imperfect) examples of what CBA/FR as conducted by a financial agency could look like.

In each case the analysis draws on the best research by economists, finance scholars, and legal scholars, all using the kinds of methods that are closest to the idealized vision of quantified CBA/FR that its proponents are asking financial agencies to pursue. 152 This review illustrates that guesstimated CBA/FR of each of the rules reviewed would (or did) require the same kinds of macroeconomic or political models used to set monetary policy, or entailed causal inferences that are unreliable under standard regulatory conditions, or both.

These case studies were also chosen to reflect representative types of major financial regulations. They focus on regulations promulgated by a variety of financial regulators: the SEC, the Federal Reserve, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), the CFTC, and the UK’s Financial Services Authority (FSA). The regulations employ a range of the kinds of regulatory instruments that are commonly analyzed or proposed for the financial markets: disclosure, governance regulations, capital requirements, activity restrictions, and transactional restrictions and process requirements. The regulations address a variety of market failures: fraud, asymmetric information more broadly, conflicts of interest, externalities (systemic crises arising from the effects of transactions on third parties), and the absence of competition. But they also give rise to a typical array of regulatory costs: compliance costs, constraints on potentially optimal private governance arrangements, smaller or less complete markets, and prohibition of potentially optimal transactions, possibly reducing economic activity and surplus. And, finally, most of the regulations were adopted following at least some conceptual CBA by the relevant agencies, and two were adopted after at least some efforts at quantification of the relevant costs and benefits.

A. Case Study #1: Control Disclosures for Public Companies153

The first case study is of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act (SOX). SOX was Congress’s response to the widespread fraud at Enron, Tyco, Worldcom , and other corporations. The core of SOX consisted of two parts 154 : (1) the creation of a quasi-public regulatory body to oversee public company audit firms—the Public Company Accounting Oversight Board (PCAOB)—and (2) the requirement of new disclosures by public companies about “control systems.” 155 Among other things, the case study illustrates the way that a common goal of financial regulation—the reduction of fraud—implicates important externalities, as well as non-market goods (such as psychological effects of fraud), which cannot be reliably reduced to precise monetary estimates, given current research technologies.

1. The SEC’s CBA of Rules Implementing SOX 404

SOX required the SEC to enact regulations to carry out the goals of SOX 404. 156 The SEC did this in August 2003, a year after SOX’s passage. 157 In its adopting release, the SEC included a 1400-word CBA, which, as noted above, was not a legal requirement for the SEC. 158 The release contained a separate 500-word analysis of the rule’s effects on efficiency, competition, and capital formation, 159 and a longer analysis under the PRA and RFA. 160 In its CBA, the SEC provided a qualitative listing but no quantification of the rule’s benefits. The benefits identified were: (1) generally to (a) enhance the quality of public company reporting and (b) increase investor confidence, and (2) specifically to (a) improve disclosure about management’s responsibility for financial statements and controls and how management discharges that responsibility, (b) encourage companies to devote adequate resources and attention to controls, (c) help companies detect fraud earlier, and (d) deter fraud or minimize its effects. The bottom-line benefit, then, was to reduce fraud. 161

The SEC also provided a qualitative listing of the rule’s direct costs (administrative burdens and fees to attorneys and auditors). The SEC noted that companies were already required to have a control system under the Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (FCPA) and that many issuers were already voluntarily providing the required disclosures, raising conceptual issues (discussed below) for what baseline and set of effects to assume in any CBA/FR of the rule—issues that the SEC did not explicitly address. The SEC provided a partial quantification of the costs of its rules under SOX 404. That estimate focused exclusively on the requirements of subsection (a) of SOX 404, disclosures by management, which the SEC estimated would cost covered companies an average of $91,000 per year. 162 The SEC explicitly noted it had no information that would allow it to quantify the costs created by subsection (b) of SOX 404, the auditor attestation requirements, which it acknowledged could be large. 163

Of note for assessing CBA/FR’s effects on public understanding, the SEC has been strongly criticized for the CBA/FR in its release—but only for the part of its CBA/FR that provided a quantitative estimate of costs, which one commentator has claimed is “off by a factor of over 48.” 164 However, this critique of the SEC’s CBA/FR is demonstrably mistaken. The SEC’s estimate was solely for SOX 404(a), while the FEI/FERF estimate was for both SOX 404(a) and 404(b). 165 For several reasons, auditor attestation costs can be expected to exceed internal costs by a multiple (as in fact has been the case). 166 The SEC explicitly acknowledged this gap in its cost estimate, 167 but the criticisms of the SEC ever since—including by SEC Commissioner Gallagher himself—have mistakenly claimed the estimate was for SOX 404 as an entirety. 168 CBA/FR advocates, in other words, have publicly and repeatedly criticized the SEC for underestimating the cost of apples and oranges when the SEC’s estimate was for the cost of apples alone. The spectacle may undermine an observer’s faith in the value of public discourse stimulated by CBA/FR.

A better critique of the SEC’s CBA/FR of SOX 404 is that it failed as conceptual CBA/FR for not identifying indirect costs of the rule. Indirect costs include potential reductions in risk-taking, dilution in strategic focus, and the opportunity costs of devoting excessive management time to compliance and working through the initial control attestation process with outside auditors, internal audit staff, and members of companies’ audit committees (which SOX required to be wholly independent for the first time). 169 While quantifying these costs would have been nearly impossible for the SEC at the time (as discussed below), the SEC could have pointed to the possibility of these costs in its rulemaking.

Conversely, the SEC in 2006 did not identify (much less quantify) increased fraud as a possible cost of the deferral of SOX 404 requirements for small and newly public companies, nor did it identify (much less quantify) increased fraud as a possible side effect (cost) of the relaxation of the SOX 404 requirements in 2007. 170 While these efforts were deregulatory in nature, they would be just as subject to CBA under Executive Order 12,866 for an executive agency as would the imposition of new regulations. 171 The fact that the more prominent CBA/FR proponents 172 do not mention these gaps in the SEC’s deregulatory rulemaking process under SOX tends to undermine their general depictions of CBA/FR as a politically neutral procedure for improving regulation generally.

2. An Overview of CBA/FR of SOX 404

Now that ten years have passed since its adoption, how might SOX 404 fare under a CBA/FR? Quantifying the costs and benefits of the rule would require multiple research tasks. These include (1) establishing better estimates of the incidence and direct costs of fraud, 173 (2) securing consensus on how to treat “transfers” for purposes of analyzing fraud, (3) generating new models and data on fraud’s externalities, (4) creating better instruments for estimating the rule’s causal effects, (5) developing better models and data on the chilling effects that the rule could have on legitimate activity, and (6) promoting better understanding of how compliance costs vary across firms and over time. Each task will be difficult and likely require a separate stream of research before any plausible quantified estimate of the costs and benefits of a rule under SOX 404 could be developed.

3. Estimating the Incidence of Fraud and Its Direct Costs

The first task is to develop better methods of measuring the incidence of corporate fraud and its direct costs. This task is a prerequisite even to a rough estimate of the effects of regulations aimed at reducing fraud, such as SOX 404. Yet, with few exceptions, research on fraud to date has only attempted to establish relationships between fraud and its correlates, and it does not present evidence of how strong these relationships are, or what the overall incidence of corporate fraud is. 174

One difficulty confronting such studies is that all concerned have incentives to hide fraud. 175 Partial observability presents challenges to empirical modeling, 176 but until recently, few researchers used models adapted to those challenges. Such models study both fraud incidence and detection together, exploiting partial overlap in indicators of fraud incidence and detection to draw better inferences about correlates of fraud overall from detected frauds. 177

Building on this work, one study exploits the collapse of Arthur Andersen to estimate an incidence of fraud among public companies at approximately fifteen percent. 178 The study also estimates that fraud generates direct losses of between twenty-two percent and forty percent of enterprise value, implying a lower bound on hidden fraud of three percent of enterprise value (0.15 × 0.22 = 0.03), or losses of over $500 billion. This study is a promising start to estimating how much fraud exists and how costly it is. But it is, as yet, unpublished and relatively isolated, 179 and it needs more scrutiny before it can provide a reliable rulemaking foundation. Future research could use more comprehensive measures of fraud, including fraud outside the scope of audits that nevertheless might be revealed by a stronger control system, such as insider trading and self-dealing (as at Enron), fraudulently obtained compensation (as at Tyco), frauds involving third parties (as at Worldcom ), or technically GAAP-compliant but deceptive accounting choices (as at Lehman).

4. How Should Transfers Be Treated?

An open conceptual issue in estimating the costs of fraud is how to treat transfers accomplished through fraud —in other words, whether to count the utility of a fraudster in estimating welfare effects of fraud. 180 Data on crime generally suggests the issue could have a significant effect on a CBA/FR of SOX 404. 181 Canonical economic theory would count the loss as zero, as would the OMB Guidance on CBA, 182 but it seems implausible as a political, policy, or legal matter for the SEC to ignore for purposes of CBA/FR of SOX 404 the losses of Enron’s defrauded investors on the ground that they were mere transfers to Ken Lay and Andrew Fastow . OMB Guidance suggests including transfers in an analysis of “distributional effects” distinct from quantified costs and benefits, 183 but that does not answer the question of how an agency should weigh the transfers in its overall CBA. 184

5. Measuring the Externalities and Psychological Costs of Fraud

If more work is needed to model the incidence of and transfers caused by fraud, no researchers have systematically attempted to study and measure the social costs of corporate fraud. Without estimates of such costs, an assessment of rules that reduce fraud, such as SOX 404, would have to remain qualitative. Research is needed both on externalities 185 and psychological costs . On externalities, consider these categories 186 : (a) fraud increases the cost of capital for all firms; 187 (b) fraud results in the misallocation of resources ; 188 (c) fraud destroys value through (costly) acquisitions and bankruptcy ; 189 (d) fraud induces precautionary costs ; 190 and (e) fraud imposes costs on non-investor third parties . 191 Consider the Madoff scandal, which imposed significant direct losses on over 15,000 individual investors, each of whom presumably had an average of two dependents or heirs, and many of whom were co-investors and borrowers with yet others, or makers of charitable donations to non-profits. 192 To date, the liquidation of the Madoff entities has generated over $700 million in expenses—all a pure loss to investors, over and above the amounts stolen by Madoff himself. 193

As a broader example, consider how fraudulent home loans (whether due to borrower fraud, lender fraud, or both) had ripple effects in the last financial bubble, partly generated through leverage and intermediation, so the one fraudulent loan would affect not only the immediate parties to the loan but also securitization lenders, sponsors, and related parties; collateralized debt obligation investors, sponsors, and related parties; structured investment vehicle investors, sponsors, and related parties; investors in the banks that sponsored those vehicles; borrower-customers of those banks, whose capital constraints and heightened risk-aversion following the crisis caused a withdrawal or increase in the cost of credit; employees and customers of businesses that failed as a result of the capital constraints generated by the banks’ losses; family members of those employees; and so on.

Psychological effects (fear, distrust, stress) can result in tangible consequences, including drug addiction, job loss, reduced income, health effects, and even suicide. In the context of securities fraud, elevated levels of post-traumatic stress disorder and related behavioral effects have been found among Madoff’s victims. 194

The take-away from these thought experiments—and they remain just that—is that the external costs of fraud are likely to exceed, perhaps by a large amount, direct transfers from victim to fraudster. As a result, the quantified benefit of SOX 404 is likely to be found not in estimating direct losses prevented, but in increasing those losses by a multiple to reflect its externalities. How do we translate anecdotal examples into more general methods for estimating the full effects of fraud on society as a whole?

In the context of SOX, only one unpublished paper attempts to estimate fraud’s social costs. 195 The authors treat widespread revelations of fraud as a “shock” to the equity premium and estimate its social effects with a macroeconomic model. For this purpose—and this is worth stressing in light of the discussion of the Taylor Rule in Part I.D above—they adapt a model used by the Treasury Department and the Federal Reserve to set monetary policy. 196 They first guesstimate that 25% to 100% of the market decline from March to July 2002 was caused by the scandals of Enron, Tyco, Worldcom , and other companies. 197 They then rely on the U.S./Fed. model to estimate that investment would fall 0.8% per year in response to a 20% decline in the stock market, guesstimating first-year impacts ranging from nineteen to fifty-seven billion dollars. 198 These projections underestimate costs if the impact of the frauds lasts longer, and could over- or underestimate costs if the economy’s response to fraud-driven equity shocks differs from responses to other kinds of shocks, or if the assumptions of the U.S./Fed. model are varied. 199

Finally, research on fraud’s social costs could draw on research on crime generally, which uses several families of methods 200 : (1) estimating hedonic models in which variation in prices affected by crime is used to infer social costs; 201 (2) surveying willingness-to-pay for a reduction in crime; 202 (3) aggregating estimates of each direct and indirect effect; 203 and (4) relating responses to surveys of crime victims to respondent wealth or income and inferring a “shadow price” for the effects of crime. 204 Each method has limitations 205 : guesstimates based on willingness-to-pay surveys have been stringently criticized as too subjective and internally inconsistent to be reliable for CBA purposes, 206 and to date these methods have not been undertaken in the context of fraud.

6. Estimating Causal Effects of SOX 404

With a better framework for estimating the incidence and costs of fraud in hand, researchers could then better estimate the benefits of regulatory changes such as SOX 404. Where a regulation is an innovation, regulators are not in a position to “study” its causal effects at all, but must forecast those effects. For SOX 404, this type of prediction would have been impossible; indeed, few observers (even hostile commentators, who had incentives to exaggerate) anticipated the full extent of the direct costs that SOX 404 would initially generate.

Ex post or retrospective studies, coupled with regulations that sunset absent re-adoption based on the result of the ex post studies, are more promising, and would be better able to enlist academic research in the service of better financial regulation. To date, however, most retrospective studies of SOX have not used research designs allowing reliable causal inferences about its effects. Instead, most researchers have used before-and-after comparisons that fail to control for contemporaneous changes in the objects of study. 207 Better are a handful of difference-in-difference studies, such as those used to study some of the effects of SOX. 208 In such studies, researchers match, as best they can, the companies affected by a regulation with unaffected companies and compare the before-and-after effects. But even those studies are commonly misleading in the kinds of rich, interdependent environments that characterize the financial markets. Long-term trends may manifest differently in the treated and nominal control group, and common factors omitted from the matching criteria that affect events in the nominal control sample may differentially affect the nominally “treated” sample, creating a spurious impression that the regulation had effects it did not actually have. 209

Better for identifying causal effects ex post are discontinuity designs, which look at the before-and-after effects of a regulation on firms just above a threshold triggering compliance and compare them with changes at firms just below the threshold. 210 However, the findings of such studies rarely generalize beyond firms “near” the discontinuity, making them of limited use in CBA/FR. 211 This point is illustrated by Figure 1, which depicts how one of the best studies of SOX 404, by Peter Iliev , used such a discontinuity design. 212 While that study provided convincing evidence on causality, it provides very limited information about SOX’s overall effects, because of how different the firms near the discontinuity are from the firms most likely to generate significant costs and benefits.

limits on external validity of single best sox study to date 213

Perhaps the best of feasible ex post studies are time-series designs studying multiple events, which were used by a small number of studies to analyze SOX 404. Leuz and coauthors studied differences-in-differences among covered and exempt groups of companies over several events in the phase-in of the rule, including extensions by the SEC of exemptions for small firms, and Arping and Sautner studied the staged phase-in for foreign firms cross-listed in the United States. 214 Neither study attempted comprehensive measurement of changes in fraud or direct and indirect costs at covered firms, but in principle these types of studies provide the best path towards a possible retrospective CBA/FR of SOX 404.

7. What Baseline and Set of Counterfactuals Should Be Used?

Even if a research design could produce reliable inferences about the effects of financial regulation, it is unclear how (if at all) to modify the results of such a study to reflect the context in which the rule was adopted. As mentioned above, the SEC’s CBA/FR of SOX 404 noted two facts about the rule’s context: (1) covered companies were already subject to the FCPA, which requires companies to have effective control systems, and (2) many companies already voluntarily made disclosures similar to ones required by the rule. These facts raise several open questions about the baselines and counterfactuals to be used in assessing the rule.

First, what baseline should be used to assess the effects of SOX? One possibility is to assume a baseline of full compliance with prior law. Another is to use a realistic baseline of average actual compliance, in which case both costs and benefits would likely be higher (reflecting the gap between full and average compliance, on the reasonable assumption that effects of new enforcement pressures from SOX would have a diminishing effect as compliance increases). A third possibility is to try to estimate levels of baseline compliance that vary with observable firm characteristics. Nothing in the SEC’s governing statutes or other relevant law resolves which baseline to use, but the answer would likely have a significant effect on any quantified CBA/FR of the rule. 215

Second, how should analysts treat indirect behavioral effects of eliciting information for purposes of CBA/FR? Suppose, for example, that disclosure reduces risk-taking (as SOX 404 may have done) not because it distracts management but simply because it prevents managers from hiding behind information asymmetries to deflect blame from losses caused by risks they caused the firm to take. Assume that in a world of symmetric information, those risks would not have been taken, but might have generated expected net gains for a firm (perhaps due to differences in risk aversion between managers and diversified shareholders). Should the lost gains due to this reduction in risk-taking be counted? Asymmetric information is treated as a market failure in conventional economics and in the OMB Guidance on CBA. Does that imply that “costs” (such as reduced risk-taking) causally attributed to elimination of some (but not all) information asymmetries should not be counted in CBA/FR? Such a question arises for all disclosure regulations, which anticipate and rely on private responses to the disclosure. 216

8. How Do Compliance Costs Vary Across Firms and over Time?

Better methods are also needed for estimating costs, even direct costs. Affected companies and their agents (who know the most about the likely direct costs of a rule) have incentives to exaggerate costs in public comments. 217 These exaggerations are evident from the strong contrasts between the FEI/FERF survey results on SOX 404 218 and the findings on direct costs from surveys by the SEC, the GAO, and CAQ, a firm catering to the audit industry. 219 Compliance costs also vary across firms. 220 The SEC’s own studies of the effects of SOX 404 221 contain information on some relevant differences, but future CBA/FR could usefully build such differences into better models of direct compliance costs, rather than relying on rationally biased inputs from private actors.

9. Modeling and Measuring Chilling Effects of Financial Regulation

Although direct costs of SOX 404 were most salient to firms, because these costs were borne directly by firms and paid out of their treasuries, indirect costs of SOX 404 may have been larger. They are likely to remain high and may increase rather than diminish over time, as direct costs typically do. Indirect costs include those flowing from changes in risk-taking and investment, which can plausibly dwarf direct costs in magnitude. SOX 404 is said to have caused changes in the risk of personal liability facing managers and directors and in the risk of reputational harms and opportunity costs created by litigation. 222 If true, difficult-to-explain and legitimate business risks may be foregone, and firms may decline to go public or otherwise avoid the burdens of the law, with resulting social costs. However, the challenges of estimating indirect costs are also larger than for direct costs. Causal inference for indirect costs is just as difficult as for a regulation’s benefits, requiring quasi-experimental research designs that will only be imperfect, even after the fact. Powerful empirical proxies for risk-taking, investment, and capital costs remain elusive and contested.

10. Summary and Illustrative Integrated Assessment Model

The previous sections have described the kind of CBA/FR of SOX 404 that could (in theory) be done today, from the distinctly advantaged after-the-fact perspective of ten years after the rule was adopted. The bottom line is that no one could hope to conduct a precise and compelling quantified CBA/FR of such a rule now or in the near future. The one component of CBA/FR that could be quantified—direct costs—has generated estimates that vary by an order of magnitude. 223 Other, larger components, including benefits from reduced fraud and indirect costs from effects on risk-taking, investment, and management, all remain unquantifiable.

To produce quantified CBA/FR, the SEC would need an “integrative assessment model” (IAM) similar to those used in estimating the social cost of carbon in climate change analysis. 224 An IAM would have to combine a sub-model of fraud incidence, a sub-model of the costs of fraud, including transfers and externalities (possibly consisting of a macroeconomic model), and a predictive empirical sub-model for how SOX 404 would affect the incidence of fraud. Indirect costs would have to be estimated in yet another sub-model.

To illustrate what an IAM might look like, consider the following: beginning with the formula for the present value of a perpetuity, 225 an annual per-firm direct cost stream for SOX 404 ranging from $300,000 to $2 million per year 226 would range from $10 to $67 million (at a three percent discount rate) or from $4 to $29 million (at a seven percent discount rate). 227 As of 2003, there were roughly 4,400 U.S. public companies covered by SOX 404, 228 producing a present value of direct costs ranging from $19 to $293 billion.

How would this compare to a possible range of benefits for SOX 404? Suppose fraud incidence was—as estimated by Dyck et al. 229 —three percent of market capitalization, on average, but could range from 50% to 200% of that estimate. These assumptions produce direct fraud costs ranging from $140 to $700 billion. Suppose SOX 404 permanently reduced annual fraud risk by an amount ranging from 1% to 10%. 230 When applied to our direct fraud cost estimates, the range of fraud reduction implies benefits from SOX 404 ranging from $2 to $84 billion. Finally, assume fraud externalities range from one to three times direct costs. 231 This implies benefits ranging from $4 to $336 billion.

illustrative quantitative cba / fr of sox 404

Table 2 summarizes. The high end of costs is far higher than the low end of benefits, producing a net cost of $289 billion, but the low end of costs is far lower than the high end of benefits, producing a net benefit of $317 billion. Depending on assumptions, guesstimated CBA suggests that SOX 404 could be a very good idea, a very bad idea, or anything in between. If one arbitrarily chose the range’s midpoint, SOX 404 created a net benefit of $9 billion. But this bottom line is highly sensitive, as reflected in Table 3, with net benefits changing by between 2 x and 13 x as one moves from low to high values for each of five major inputs into the illustrative IAM.

sensitivity of output of illustrative iam to inputs

This illustrative IAM is crude: it implicitly resolves all of the open issues reviewed above and uses many assumptions. The IAM could be challenged on numerous fronts: (a) indirect costs are omitted; (b) open issues on baselines and counterfactuals are resolved in favor of higher cost estimates, but discounted by an arbitrary thirty percent; (c) the current run-rate for direct costs is assumed to last indefinitely, contrary to the SEC’s survey of SOX 404 costs that suggests that costs can be expected to fall; 232 (d) transfers from U.S. to non-U.S. persons are ignored; (e) transfers from fraud victims to other shareholders are counted; (f) the ratio of externalities to transfers is borrowed from research on crime, not fraud; (g) discount rates are from OMB Guidance; (h) the fraud reduction effect is assumed to be a one-time permanent reduction; ( i ) the rate of fraud reduction is derived from a before-and-after study that may wrongly misattribute changes to SOX; (j) the rate of fraud reduction is derived from studies of earnings, and not the full range of fraud that SOX might reduce; and so on. A change in any of these assumptions would change the bottom line. This list of serious debatable limits could be extended for many pages. Any serious contest between opposed analysts would add to the upper ends of ranges of both costs and benefits. 233

B. Case Study #2: Independent Boards for Mutual Funds

The second case study is of the mutual fund governance rules proposed by the SEC in the wake of the market-timing scandals of the early 2000s. Together with the review of the Chamber of Commerce case in Part II.B, this case study illustrates, among other things, how judicial review of CBA can penalize an agency for transparency about the limits of its ability to quantify the costs and benefits of a rule.

The ill-fated mutual fund governance rules had their origins in 2003, when New York Attorney General Eliot Spitzer ended his prepared remarks at a Harvard Law School reunion event with a dramatic J’accuse ! Pointing a finger at a fellow panelist—a lawyer from Fidelity Management 234 —Spitzer announced that his office was about to reveal widespread fraud in the mutual fund industry. Over the next year, twenty-six advisory companies settled cases alleging violations of the securities laws in which select investors were permitted to harm funds and other investors by engaging in late or frequent trading that was either contrary to SEC rules or contrary to disclosed fund policies. 235

Scandals at this scale had not hit the fund industry in decades, and while the wrongdoing alleged varied from fund complex to fund complex, the most troubling charges involved conflicts of interest between the fund advisors and the funds they advised. 236 Conflict-of-interest transactions had been banned in 1940, but because many conflict-of-interest transactions could benefit funds, the SEC had adopted a series of exemptions, subject to a fund’s meeting set conditions. 237 In 2001, the SEC had tightened the conditions, increasing the share of independent directors from forty percent to a majority for funds wanting to use the exemptions (as most funds wanted).

1. The Rules

In response to the scandals highlighted by Attorney General Spitzer, the SEC proposed further tightening of the conditions for exemption, (1) requiring a fund’s board to contain seventy-five percent independent directors and (2) adding a requirement that a fund board chair be independent of the advisor. 238 The latter requirement was anathema to Fidelity Management—one of the largest fund complexes, privately held, and dominated by its founder, Ned Johnson, who chaired boards of all 292 funds advised by Fidelity. 239 Fidelity paid for a study that found a negative correlation between independent board chairs and fund performance but which acknowledged that the correlation could be due to “other important differences that may have impacted performance results,” such as the prevalence of split chairs in bank-sponsored fund groups. 240

The SEC adopted the more stringent conditions by a three-to-two partisan vote in August 2004. In its rule release, the SEC included a 1,680-word CBA/FR and a lengthier discussion of the conditions’ benefits in its general assessment of the conditions. 241 The CBA/FR was qualitative, and the rule was justified because, in the SEC’s view, independent directors and chairs were “more likely to be primarily loyal to the fund shareholders rather than the fund adviser”; 242 in addition, the independent directors and chairs were more likely to effectively manage conflicts of interest such as those involved in the 2003 scandals. 243 The SEC explicitly noted it had not conducted a quantified CBA/FR, as it could not quantify either costs or benefits. The agency also stated that it was “not aware of any conclusive research that demonstrates that the hiring of an independent chairman will improve fund performance or reduce expenses, or the reverse.” 244 Within weeks, Fidelity persuaded Senator Judd Gregg (a Republican from New Hampshire) to include a rider to an omnibus bill; 245 the rider required the SEC to study the need for tightened conditions, resulting in an SEC study that was released in April 2005. That study contained seventy-seven pages of conceptual CBA/FR, showing that the Fidelity-commissioned study was sensitive to assumptions and could not reliably establish what it purported to show. After the SEC conducted the study, the Chamber of Commerce sued to overturn the rule under the APA and the ICA, a suit that ended in Chamber of Commerce v. SEC as described in Part II. 246

2. The Aftermath of Chamber of Commerce II

After the second Chamber of Commerce decision, 247 the SEC requested that the SEC’s Chief Economist 248 reevaluate the governance rules yet again. That request led to two memos—publicly released with a request for public comment.

In those memos, the Chief Economist concluded that (1) more independent boards were more likely to better protect investors, but (2) little evidence existed to establish that board composition would create higher returns. 249 These two conclusions, seemingly in tension, could be reconciled by one or more of three further conclusions: (a) “no sound structural model [exists] . . . to isolate the effect of a . . . board decision on performance”; (b) “inherent limitations to data and statistical tools . . . may render it difficult for research to identify relations that . . . may be economically significant”; or (c) “there may not be a unique relation between governance and performance.” 250 In other words, the state of finance research was such that no CBA/FR of the mutual fund governance rules was feasible. At the same time, economic theory (particularly agency cost theory) and the Chief Economist’s judgment, based on the research reviewed in the memos, supported a qualitative judgment that the rules would better protect investors.

3. What Would CBA of the Mutual Fund Governance Rules Require?

Implicit in the Chief Economist’s memos is a sketch of what quantified CBA/FR of the governance rules would look like. As the memos noted, the best board structure (in terms of independence) depends

on the . . . consequences of increasing the influence of outsiders . . . . [ O] utsiders may bring expertise and independence [and] improve the quality of management decisions and manage conflicts of interest that insiders have, thereby increasing the value of the firm [but] may lack information about the “inner-workings” of the firm and other firm-specific knowledge [which if] difficult to extract . . . may diminish the quality of management decisions and reduce the value of the firm. 251

Because this tradeoff may vary by fund, a fixed minimum share of independent directors may benefit investors in one fund by preventing an advisor from influencing the board to nominate too few independent directors. The same minimum may harm investors in another fund by raising the level of independence beyond the optimum for that fund.

Because optimal boards likely vary, however, and because board structure is only one of many factors that influence firm value, an empirical comparison of value at funds with more independent directors in the pre-rule context would not generate reliable information about the effect of the rules. Governance scholars have known this fact—that cross-sectional observational studies produce only weak information about the merits of endogenously chosen governance structures—for some time. 252 A source of governance variation that is exogenous with respect to fund value is a necessary but insufficient condition for identifying the average effect of a proposed rule about the feature. Few exogenous sources of variation for fund governance exist, other than as a result of SEC rule changes—and even for those changes, the effects they have caused are likely to be sufficiently small as to be difficult to discover, even with the best cross-sectional modeling.

This identification challenge is fundamental and greatly undermines the reliability of any guesstimated CBA/FR of rules on fund (or corporate) governance. 253 The difficulty is even more severe than it was in the SOX case study because the plausible importance of any detail of governance is lower for SOX, which combined multiple institutional and enforcement changes. Anything that changes fund values—for example, anything that changes the value of a fund’s investments—can confound the ability of researchers to identify the effects of governance changes. Fund investment values undergo changes that are continuous and large (money funds aside) relative to the effect of governance details. A shift from fifty percent to seventy-five percent independent directors will not have an effect on value approaching a small fraction of common market-affecting events. 254 In the language of econometrics, the “power” of statistical tests given available data is too weak to detect, much less reliably and precisely quantify, the effects of most governance changes—even if we had examples of changes that were plausibly exogenous. All of these points are made plain in the Chief Economist’s memos, even if they were not explained in the SEC’s releases or subsequent D.C. Circuit opinions. 255

To be sure, any change in governance mandates will generate adjustment costs—the focus of both the SEC in the “cost” section of its rule release and of the Chamber of Commerce in its lawsuit—that could be quantified (or at least bounded) based on survey evidence. But if benefits of a rule cannot be quantified, and larger potential costs of the rule due to fund performance cannot be quantified, it remains unclear why the failure to quantify adjustment costs is a significant failing or how (if provided) such information would materially improve public understanding of the effects of the rule. This point is even more compelling when, as here, even the quantifications would vary depending on private responses that could not be forecast with any precision, as the D.C. Circuit acknowledged in Chamber of Commerce . Put differently, litigation challenging the SEC’s rule focused on an immaterial subset of the likely costs and benefits of the rule, and had the SEC done exactly what the D.C. Circuit ultimately said it had to do, the result would likely have had no material effect on any assessment of the rule. Yet one would not know this from reading the D.C. Circuit’s opinions or much of the commentary on the case. 256 The litigation is a perfect example of how CBA law—here, judicial review of CBA/FR—can obscure more than illuminate.

4. The Aftermath of the Aftermath

Because it was unclear if the Chief Economist’s memos represented the end or the beginning of another stage in the SEC’s efforts to revise governance rules, Fidelity filed a 141-page comment in response, including a twenty-two-page analysis of the Chief Economist’s memos by me (for which I was paid a fee, giving me a financial interest in this topic). 257 In my analysis, I critiqued the memos on the ground that the research used to support the qualitative conclusion that the rules would better protect investors was weak, inconsistent, and at times at odds with the summary in the memos. I also outlined a number of potential costs to the proposed rules that had not been noted in the Chief Economist’s memos. 258

Subsequently, the SEC has taken no more action to re-propose its governance reforms. What is unclear, however, is whether its decision was based on a genuine change of policy. Two less optimistic possibilities exist: (1) between Chamber of Commerce II and the SEC’s giving up on the rules, the SEC Chair changed identity (William Donaldson was replaced by Christopher Cox); and (2) the ongoing litigation threat, coupled with the fact that reliable quantified CBA/FR for the rules remains unfeasible, led the SEC not to want to risk another morale-draining, resource-depleting court loss, 259 even if it continued to believe that the governance rules would benefit investors at a low cost. In favor of the last possibility is the fact that the Chief Economist’s memos were released after Christopher Cox became Chairman, but they supported re-adoption, and nothing in the public commentary (including my comment) provided any compelling quantitative reason for the SEC to change its mind. While the qualitative reasoning in the public comments may be part of the explanation, a dysfunctional system of judicial review seems likely to be a bigger part of the explanation.

C. Case Study #3: Heightened Capital Requirements for Banks

The third case study is of bank capital rule reforms adopted in the wake of the 2008 to 2009 financial crisis. Among other things, the case study illustrates how difficult it is to quantify one of the core benefits of a great number—perhaps the majority—of financial regulations: reductions in systemic risk. The difficulty is in part due to the relatively small number of comparable crises from which to draw reliable inferences about the effects of crises or the effects of regulations on them.

“[ Y] ou only find out who is swimming naked when the tide goes out.” 260 Warren Buffett’s perhaps self-congratulatory moral was occasioned by losses facing casualty insurers after 9/11, but it captures a central fact of the 2008 crisis: banks were revealed to be grossly undercapitalized for risks they had been running. Undercapitalization was evident in the failures of both commercial banks—Washington Mutual, Wachovia—and investment banks—Lehman, Bear Stearns. But it was also true of the more than 700 banks bailed out by the United States. 261 Even the “best” performing U.S. banks during the crisis lost significant amounts of money, needed to raise capital on terms suggesting pre-crisis undercapitalization, 262 and would have failed without massive infusions of liquidity by the Federal Reserve, through near-zero interest rates and three rounds of “quantitative easing,” six years after the crisis began. 263

Capital shortfalls were global but not universal. Banks in the United Kingdom, France, Germany, and Belgium failed or needed government support to stay open, while banks in Canada and Australia did not, in part due to tight capital regulation. 264 In a cross-section of banks, those with more capital and those based in countries with more stringent capital regulation did better than banks elsewhere, controlling for other factors. 265

1. Regulatory Response

It was thus inevitable that regulators around the world would impose new, higher capital requirements. Capital regulation is coordinated for global banks (on a voluntary multilateral basis) by the Bank for International Settlements (BIS) based in Basel. More precisely, BIS hosts the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (Basel Committee), composed of members from twenty-seven countries, which from time to time reaches consensus on a unified set of capital regulations for banks. 266 Bank regulators in the member countries then transpose the consensus to national regulation.

Each U.S. banking agency (the Federal Reserve, the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), and the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC)) 267 participates in the Basel Committee. 268 Following the crisis, the Committee hosted talks on new capital guidelines (called Basel III to distinguish them from two prior guidelines). This new round focused on tougher capital guidelines for large banks engaged in cross-border transactions or activities with a lack of substitutes, 269 and on liquidity requirements—with the aim of addressing liquidity risks that played a greater role in 2008 than in prior crises. 270 The new capital guidelines included leverage ratios so banks will need to hold a minimum ratio of capital to assets, even if those assets nominally have a low level of risk, such as highly rated mortgage-backed securities. 271 Other requirements in the guidelines included more common equity; tougher treatment for credit default swaps and counterparty risk; securitizations; and risk management; and a surcharge for the very largest, most complex, and interconnected banks, known as “systemically important financial institutions,” or SIFIs. 272 The Committee circulated capital guidelines in December 2010 (revised in June 2011) and liquidity guidelines in January 2013. The U.S. agencies proposed capital requirements for U.S. banks in August 2012, eliciting over 2,500 comments before being finalized in October 2013, and proposed new liquidity requirements in November 2013. 273

2. CBA/FR of Basel III

Although U.S. banking agencies briefly discussed costs in reviewing comments on their rules, 274 none of the U.S. banking regulators included formal CBA in transposing Basel III to U.S. law. However, the Basel Committee itself, in consultation with the International Monetary Fund, published its own CBA/F R . 275 The Committee elicited CBA/FR that focused on costs to its members (central banks and bank regulatory agencies), twenty-three of which obtained data and analyses from 263 large banks worldwide. 276 Subsequently, the Fed’s counterpart in the United Kingdom (then the FSA) 277 extended the Basel Committee’s CBA/FR in published white papers. 278

Collectively, the work of the Basel Committee and the FSA on Basel III’s higher capital rules provides another detailed illustration of what CBA/FR looks like for a financial regulation with large if narrow significance. A review of these publications does not leave a reader with much confidence in using guesstimated CBA/FR to guide regulation. CBA/FR of the new rules required complex social and economic predictions. First, the analysis had to estimate benefits of heightened capital and liquidity requirements; those benefits were identified as less frequent and/or severe financial crises. Two sub-models were needed, one to estimate the cost of a crisis and one to predict the frequency of crises. The CBA/FR then faced the challenge of forecasting the causal effect of the requirements on each modeled relationship (incidence and effects). Finally, the CBA/FR had to estimate the costs of the requirements—posited to be lower lending by the banks subject to the rules. Each of these models is discussed below.

3. Costs of a Financial Crisis

Focus first on the costs of a crisis. One pair of commentators has suggested that this element of CBA/FR should be “easy”: “Agreement on a figure in the range 150 billion to 3 trillion dollars (viz. a crisis cost between 1 percent and 20 percent of US GDP . . .) would seem relatively easy to reach given the widely respected estimates of Reinhart and Rogoff .” 279 Unfortunately, this view is too sanguine by more than half. Other estimates of the costs of financial crises range from 90% to 350% of world GDP (Bank of England); 18% to 48% of UK GDP (FSA 42); and 10% to 210% of UK GDP. 280

To state the obvious: these ranges do not even overlap. The high end of Posner and Weyl’s range (20% of U.S. GDP) is less than one-fourth of the low end of the Bank of England’s range and is barely above the low end of the FSA’s range. The high end of the Bank of England’s estimate is seventeen times that of Posner and Weyl’s , and Yan et al.’s estimate is eleven-and-a-half times larger than Posner and Weyl’s . In absolute, comparable, present value dollars, these differences are enormous: trillions, not billions.

One may object, fairly, that Posner and Weyl’s estimate is for all future crises, whereas the other ranges are for the recent crisis. But there are two responses. First, with respect to the recent crisis, the ranges still vary substantially. Second, as discussed more below, no consensus approach exists to resolve which historical data one should use in estimating the cost of future crises. Data from 1929, included in Reinhart and Rogoff , on which Posner and Weyl rely, 281 are not obviously more or equally relevant to future crises than data from 2008. A longer set of historical data has the advantage of allowing costs to vary with factors that fluctuate or cycle over decades, and dampens the effect of differences of estimated costs of any particular crisis. A shorter set of data from more recent periods has several advantages as well. First, a shorter dataset promotes better modeling of current economic, legal, and political conditions, including the centrality of finance to the economy, 282 which has arguably increased over time; it also allows one to account for the presence of laws and institutions that socialize some of the risks of crises, such as FDIC deposit insurance, and that did not exist in 1929. Second, a shorter dataset enables one to reduce the number of disputes that can be expected over which crises to include in the dataset. Given the tradeoffs between a shorter and a longer dataset, neither choice clearly dominates.

An examination of CBA/FR conducted for the Basel Committee reveals methodologies and estimates of the costs of crises more disparate than in the studies just summarized. The Committee reviewed twenty-one studies. Two provided estimates of peak-to-trough losses during the crises studied, while thirteen provided cumulative loss estimates. The present value of the average cost in the latter studies ranged from 16% to 302% of pre-crisis GDP (sometimes measured against domestic GDP, sometimes global). Several include a lower bound of zero( !), 283 while the highest upper bound was 1041% of pre-crisis GDP. One study presented results from two methods that varied at the mean by a factor of five and at the high end by a factor of ten. 284

The Basel Committee’s qualitative summary is “that results in the literature are surprisingly consistent.” 285 But this conclusion is inconsistent with the committee’s statement elsewhere in its report that one can find “a significant range of crisis outcomes across studies and individual episodes.” 286 Presumably, the “significant range” of outcomes is “surprisingly consistent” when measured against prior expectations that the results would lack coherence altogether.

The table summarizing the committee’s findings, 287 converted into Figure 2 here, shows the sensitivity of the results to assumptions and methodological choices. The primary drivers of the sensitivity of results are: (1) selection of historical data points; (2) assumptions about whether economic losses will be permanent or temporary, and if temporary, how long crises will last; and (3) what policy response will be triggered by the crisis. For each driver, a number of choices must be made, and each choice has large effects on the bottom line of the CBA/FR.

range of estimates of costs of financial crisis 288

For the simplest driver—choice of data—at least three contestable choices are required. First, a “financial crisis” must be defined: crises can be subjectively and judgmentally chosen (“I know it when I see it” approach) 289 or objectively chosen, and either way can be based on a variety of data, including data regarding market volatility, 290 bank runs, 291 bank closures or nationalizations, 292 bank bailouts, 293 stock market declines, 294 and ratios of non-performing loans to bank assets. 295 Some distinguish banking from market crises; others include banking crises as a subset of financial crises. 296 Second, time periods must be chosen—both for the overall dataset (how far back to go in history?) and for each crisis (because the duration of a crisis affects the count and size of effects). 297 Third, one must decide what geographic scope to consider: should one consider only crises in the United States, in developed countries (and if so, how to define “developed”?), or all countries?

These choices have large effects on outputs. One study of the costs of financial crises presents two historical samples, with its bottom line estimate doubling depending on which sample is used. 298 Even over the same historical period, one study counts 160 banking crises, including many that caused relatively small losses, reducing the average loss caused by the crises counted, while another study counts twenty-three, which caused large average losses. 299 The differences are attributable to (a) basic definitional choices; (b) whether to count poor, developing nations or nations with poorly developed financial markets; and (c) how (and whether) to count countries that experienced multiple crises close in time: if all crises are counted separately, the average cost falls, because some of the crises are brief episodes paving the way to a larger crisis. 300

Further illustrating the fragility of cost-of-crisis models is the recent kerfuffle involving Reinhart and Rogoff (R&R), on whose “widely respected estimates” Posner and Weyl rely. R&R’s publications on the effects of crises turned out to be indisputably 301 flawed because of a spreadsheet error that went undetected for over three years 302 (in spite of the fact that the study was cited prominently in policy debates). 303 While the spreadsheet error caused R&R’s analysis to drop data for five countries they intended to include, the error had no effect on their estimates of the direct costs of financial crises—that is, the fiscal costs incurred by governments attempting to resolve crises. However, the error did affect estimates of the indirect costs of financial crises—that is, the depressive effects on growth caused by higher levels of debt incurred as part of a policy response. As discussed below, whether and how to count indirect effects of policy responses are further sources of sensitivity in modeling the cost of crises. The same researchers who discovered the spreadsheet error also challenged separate choices by R&R in their analyses—what the critics termed a “selective exclusion of . . . data” (for Australia, New Zealand, and Canada) and an “unconventional weighting of summary statistics” that amplified the effects of exclusion of New Zealand. 304 While R&R disagree on these points, they do so in part on the ground that their work is historical, consisting of “archival research, involving constant judgments at every step.” 305

Even if observers agreed on historical crises to estimate the cost of future crises, two additional output-sensitive inputs—temporary versus permanent effects and policy responses—intensify the unreliability of CBA/FR of Basel III. Some studies assume the effects of a crisis on the economy are transient—that is, a crisis causes a temporary drop in activity, followed eventually by higher-than-normal “catch-up” growth, bringing long-term output trends back to where they would have been without the crisis. Other studies assume that the effects are permanent—that is, economic activity never catches up to where it would have been without the crisis. If one takes the median of the average of estimated losses across studies, as the authors of the BCBS 173 did, the difference caused by this one assumption triples the losses. 306 If harms are large (for example, 158% of pre-crisis GDP in BCBS 173), then differences between permanent-harm and temporary-harm models are even larger—up to a hundred times larger. 307 A related force increasing the sensitivity of results in permanent-harm models—which by definition extend into the indefinite future—is the choice of discount rate. 308

A third source of sensitivity of social costs to modeling assumptions is perhaps the most troubling for anyone hoping CBA/FR can produce reliable information: the political and policy response to the crisis. As the last crisis reminded us, a major financial crisis can provoke a range of policy responses. Politicians may bail out banks; tighten, loosen, or repeal regulations; increase liquidity through conventional monetary policy (cutting interest rates) and less conventional instruments (“quantitative easing”); stimulate activity directly with government spending or tax cuts; other responses; or some combination. Each response can have benefits and costs, ranging from lending constraints, moral hazard, and the future frequency of crises; inflation; deficits; debt ; and reduced medium- to long-term growth. These policy responses can vary in intensity as well. Depending on the policy response, the effect of a crisis can vary significantly, and the models reviewed in the Basel Committee CBA/FR make assumptions about the policy responses and their effects.

To predict policy responses, CBA/FR must include what amounts to political speculation. For if economic inputs to CBA/FR models are uncertain, political inputs are even more so. 309 To see this, simply note the varying policy responses across developed economies to the recent crisis. The United States created a very large (relative to the economy or the tax base) fiscal stimulus through deficit spending, while the United Kingdom “committed itself to early fiscal retrenchment.” 310 The United States implemented the most aggressive monetary program in history, through the novel technique of buying massive amounts of mortgage-backed and other fixed income securities, while the European Central Bank remained more focused on preventing inflation, and the Bank of Japan’s balance sheet increased only slightly over the crisis period. 311 Policy responses also change in response to learning (or claims to learning) from past crises—compare recent U.S. monetary and fiscal policy to responses to the Great Depression 312 and to that of Japan during the 1990s 313 —but that implies that predicting future policy requires predicting the future path of economic theory and the results of retrospective analyses of past policy interventions. This is not to mention financial rescue programs, such as TARP.

These are not second-order considerations. Informed observers have attributed much of the difference in the duration of the current U.S. recession, on the one hand, and the contemporaneous U.K. recession and the historical U.S. Great Depression, on the other hand, to policy responses. 314 Should the current legitimacy of otherwise desirable regulation turn, to any significant degree, on debates or assumptions about predictions of future politics? That is what CBA/FR advocates effectively, if tacitly, presume. 315

4. Frequency of Financial Crises

Even if the costs of financial crises could be estimated with precision and reliability, these costs would have to be paired with estimates of the frequency of crises to arrive at an estimate of the benefit from regulations that reduce crises’ frequency. This modeling faces similar challenges as estimating effects: subjectivity in selection among relatively small numbers of historical data points and sensitivity of results to choice of data points. The Basel Committee simply took average frequencies from two studies 316 over an arbitrarily chosen period and set of countries (1985 to 2009 for G10 and BCBS countries, except Russia and China, which were included from 1992 on) and made the heroic assumption that this average was a good estimate of the probability of a crisis for any given year and country. 317

The FSA, by contrast, used a longer time period (1970 to 2007), a narrower set of countries (OECD countries), and relied on a multivariable logit approach relating the likelihood of a crisis in a given year “to a vector of explanatory variables,” with observed crises in the past coded one and non-crisis years coded zero. 318 This approach relies on the logistic cumulative distribution to predict future crises and is an improvement over BCBS 173 if interdependencies among time-varying observables affect crisis frequency, as seems likely. For example, housing prices have varied over time, and crises often coincide with (partly causing, partly being caused by) bubbles in housing prices, so crisis odds would not be uniform over time but would vary in cycles and across countries. However, the small number of crises that can be modeled this way (FSA 38’s data included fourteen) limits the value of this approach, in statistical degrees of freedom and in robustness, and the functional form imposes assumptions on the shape of the distribution of crisis probabilities that is nowhere defended in the FSA’s publications.

Because of differences in approach, the FSA’s results differ markedly from the Committee’s results. BCBS 173 reports an estimated baseline probability of a crisis per year for all countries of 4.5%. 319 FSA 38 reports a baseline probability ranging from 0.7% (for Germany) to 21.7% (for the United Kingdom)—that is, from one-sixth to five times the estimate used by BCBS 173. 320 Again, the sensitivity of outputs to assumptions illustrates how fragile CBA/FR of capital regulation remains. 321

5. Effects of Higher Capital Requirements on Financial Crises

A third task necessary to estimate the benefits of higher capital requirements is to estimate how higher capital will affect the frequency and effects of future crises. The challenges are similar to those outlined in the case studies of SOX and mutual fund governance above, if slightly less difficult. The challenges are less difficult because capital levels have a more mechanical relationship to bank failure than disclosure and governance regulations have to fraud and fund performance, respectively. If a bank’s capital falls below zero, it is by definition insolvent and will be either closed, nationalized, or bailed out (and/or suffer a bank run)—all of which (at least by most definitions) feed directly into the occurrence of a financial crisis.

Nevertheless, the modeling exercise remains difficult here, too, and includes a long list of challenges. Three are reviewed here: (1) baselines; (2) packages ; and (3) international externalities. 322 The first question in any CBA is what baseline to use. Similar to the effect of fraud revelation on disclosure practices in the SOX case study, financial crises stimulate banks to raise their capital levels even without regulatory reform, as private actors increase the price of lending or investing in now apparently riskier banks. So how should one measure the effect of a regulatory mandate for new capital—against the baseline of pre-crisis capital levels, or against levels that could be expected in the wake of the crisis without the regulation? The argument for the former—advanced in FSA 42—is that “banks will tend to relax their post-crisis holdings of capital as the economic cycle strengthens.” 323 This seems sensible as a rough prediction, but it is not anchored in an equilibrium model of bank behavior. After all, banks observe the same indicia of the probability of a crisis as used in the FSA’s CBA/FR of Basel III. Bank investors can observe those indicia and bank capital levels, so why should we assume that bank capital levels only subside, rather than rise and fall as the risk of a systemic crisis rises and falls? It may be that private actors lack sufficient incentives to demand that an optimal level of capital be retained by banks, but for CBA/FR of capital requirements, the baseline itself—the capital that private actors would demand—is likely to change over time in unpredictable ways.

Part of the reason that private actors may lack incentives to demand that banks retain optimal capital is that they face moral hazard due to the likelihood of bailouts and other policy interventions. But that fact calls into question the validity of using pre-crisis capital levels as appropriate baselines altogether. Has moral hazard increased, decreased, or remained the same after the bailouts of 2008? Lehman failed, and Bear Stearns and Merrill Lynch were forced to sell at fire-sale prices—so perhaps investors are now less certain about future bailouts. But, of course, more than 700 U.S. banks were bailed out, 324 not to mention the indirect bailouts through the various liquidity facilities established by the Federal Reserve Board—so perhaps investors face even more moral hazard than before. FSA 42 asserts that the pre-crisis period was one in which “banks’ decisions . . . were not distorted by the immediate influence of the crisis or regulators’ response to the crisis.” 325 But it presents no evidence to support that assertion. Any rational actor who anticipates a crisis should, given policy responses to past crises, also anticipate that a bailout may occur with some probability, and the capital levels it will demand will be affected by that anticipation. The better point, then, is that a model of the effect of future capital regulation should start with a baseline that explicitly takes into account moral hazard as a permanent condition of financial markets without adequate regulation. However, establishing such a baseline would require estimating the subsidy provided by the moral hazard to bank investors—a task not yet convincingly tackled by researchers.

Another challenge is that Basel III consists of a package of reforms, not one reform. As FSA 42 notes, if the probability of a crisis is non-linear in the level of bank capital, as assumed in a logit model (and as seems likely), then the effect on that probability of each piece of the reform package will depend on the sequence in which the pieces are adopted. 326 As with SOX, the best one may be able to do in estimating the causal impact of a package of reforms is to evaluate the package as a whole. For the CBA/FR of any given package of reforms, this is not a critical problem, but it does undermine the value of CBA/FR because it allows regulators to determine (to an extent) what is being evaluated—and may allow a package to include some reforms that are net positive (if evaluated on their own) with other reforms that are net negative (if evaluated on their own), as long as the former outweigh the latter.

A third challenge to estimating the causal impact of Basel III, also noted in FSA 42, 327 is that it is a voluntary multilateral initiative, which means that it will be implemented in different ways at different times in different countries. Implementation in one country will affect how banks in other countries act, independent of the effect of implementation by their own regulators. If, for example, U.K. banks are required to increase capital, they may not only reduce lending but focus continued lending on geographies or sectors where interest margins are highest, which in turn may affect currency and trade flows. An increase in U.S. capital regulation under Basel III, being evaluated in a CBA/FR by a U.S. regulator, should take into account the simultaneous shift in lending activity by U.K. banks, as well as the direct effect on U.S. banks. In a global financial market, the externalities of regulation create modeling difficulties of their own—adding yet more necessary assumptions regarding how the regulations will actually affect the probability or impact of future crises.

6. Costs of Higher Capital Requirements: Less Lending?

Finally, the costs of higher capital requirements must be estimated. The standard framework, employed by the Basel Committee and the FSA, 328 is to assume that a bank required to hold an increased amount of capital will raise corporate borrowing costs and so cut lending. The reasoning is simple: banks must pay their investors a minimum expected rate of return on their invested capital; if more capital is required, the bank will have to generate greater return; to generate a higher return, a bank must charge more to its borrowers; at a higher cost of borrowing, less lending will occur. The model further assumes that with lower lending by banks, economic output will fall.

As with the models of the benefits of capital requirements, however, models of the effects on the amount of lending (and its knock-on effects on output) require numerous contestable assumptions, and their outputs are sensitive to those assumptions. Among the assumptions are: (a) the cost of bank equity and whether it will fall in response to the change in capital levels required by the rule; (b) the ability of borrowers to substitute among different sources of financing (and at what cost); and (c) how non-bank sources will be affected by an increase in bank capital requirements and the reduction in risks and effects of financial crises. 329 Each has major impacts on the output of the cost model alone.

The uncertainties associated with these assumptions are underscored by the fact that one prominent set of economists believes the social costs of higher capital requirements “would be, if there were any at all, very small.” 330 The authors point out that higher taxes, if paid by banks as a result of shifting from debt to equity finance in response to capital requirements, are not a social cost, because the shift reduces the distortive effects of a socially harmful tax code. 331 The authors argue that moral hazard induces banks to remain larger than is socially efficient, so that even if higher capital induced large banks to shrink, the overall impact on lending would be offset by increases in lending by other banks or financial institutions. 332 By contrast, the Basel Committee, based on its modeling and inputs from self-interested banks, concluded that the proposed requirements in Basel III would reduce steady-state output (gross domestic product) by between 0.25 and 0.92 percentage points, 333 which translates into $1.4 trillion in present value terms at the mid-point of this range for the United States alone. As with estimates of benefits, respectable CBA/FR opinions vary in their assessments of the present value of Basel III’s costs by more than $1 trillion.

D. Case Study #4: The Volcker Rule

The fourth case study also focuses on a rule emerging from the financial crisis: section 619 of the Dodd-Frank Act, colloquially known as the “Volcker Rule.” That rule bans U.S. banks from speculating for their own account (that is, from engaging in “proprietary trading” or holding “ownership interests” in hedge or private equity funds, subject to a number of exceptions). 334 This case study reinforces the points made in the prior case study, and also illustrates how difficult it is to assess many important kinds of financial regulations in advance, given the lack of any past data on how new markets will operate.

Specific regulations implementing the Volcker Rule were approved (after many delays) in December 2013 and went into effect on April 1, 2014. 335 The formal releases published by the financial agencies in the Federal Register contain no general CBA/FR, presumably because (1) as discussed in Part II.A, no general CBA/FR mandate exists for those agencies; (2) the statutory requirement for and authorization of the rules is part of the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956, 336 which does not contain any equivalent to the requirement in the securities laws that the SEC consider “efficiency” or in the commodities laws that the CFTC consider costs and benefits; 337 and (3) nothing in the language of section 619 requires CBA. 338 The formal rulemaking contained limited cost-related information in its analyses under the RFA and the PRA 339 but no information about benefits or non-compliance costs.

The OCC, however, did release separately a CBA/FR of the Volcker Rule. 340 It identified a number of “non-monetized” (qualitative) benefits: improved supervision by bank regulators (due to metrics reporting required by the rule); better management of risk by bank managers (for the same reason); reduced conflicts of interest; protecting “core banking services” and improved bank safety and soundness (reduced risk of bank failures); reduced “tail risk” from trading activities and reduced risks of financial crises; improved corporate governance of banks resulting from reduced stock market liquidity; and reduced harms caused by excess liquidity. 341 As the OCC noted, “benefits of the regulation can be difficult to quantify including the value of enhanced economic stability.” 342

The OCC also identified a number of costs. For a subset, the OCC provides quantified estimates: compliance costs ($405 to $541 million); additional capital costs for permissible investments in covered funds ($0 to $165 million); the OCC’s own costs of supervising compliance with the new rule ($10 million); and a one-time hit to the value of assets owned by banks but restricted by the rule, resulting from reductions in demand for those assets due to the rule. For the last type of cost, the OCC drew on academic research estimating a similar haircut in corporate bond values when bonds are downgraded by credit rating agencies and insurance companies (subject to regulations limiting their ownership of junk bonds) are forced to sell such bonds, deriving a range of costs from $0 to $3.6 billion.

However, the types of costs that are likely to be the largest ongoing costs were not quantified. Foremost among these non-quantified costs is the reduced liquidity in markets where banks were significant trading participants, particularly arising from inter-dealer trading, which is not treated as a permissible source of “customer” demand under the rule. 343 Banks, as a result, will not be able to hold certain assets as “inventory,” which will reduce liquidity in the markets for those assets and make it harder for banks to share risk with other banks when permissible customer-driven trading results in banks’ taking on large blocks of equities. As a result, banks may incur higher costs to hedge or shed those risks, or face more difficulties in managing risks. Further, the reduction in liquidity caused by the ban on inter-dealer trading will likely reduce the depth of those markets and the ability of issuers to raise capital in those markets. 344 Another potential cost of the rule is similar to one noted above for the Basel III rules: migration of trading activity to non- or less-regulated “shadow” banks, which could pose systemic risks, offsetting (and possibly exceeding) the benefits of risk reduction within the banking system.

In sum, as with the foregoing case studies, the OCC’s CBA/FR did not include a quantification of the benefits and only quantified a subset—and likely a small portion—of the costs of the Volcker Rule. The result was that the OCC confidently categorized the rule as “major” for purposes of the CRA, 345 because that categorization only requires bounding the rule’s costs, but did not reach any conclusion about the rule’s net costs and benefits.

Could the agencies go beyond conceptual CBA and conduct a reliable, precise, quantified CBA/FR? The short answer is no. There is simply no historical data on which anyone could base a reliable estimate of the benefits of preventing banks from engaging in proprietary trading or investing in hedge and private equity funds. Any effort to quantify those benefits will run straight up against the difficulties described in the case studies above. While Basel III capital rules address the “liability” side of a bank’s balance sheet, and the Volcker Rule addresses its “asset” side, both rules have as a core intended benefit the reduction in the frequency and magnitude of systemic financial crises. Thus, as with Basel III, any complete quantified CBA/FR of the Volcker Rule would require the same components discussed above for Basel III to estimate the costs and frequency of financial crises (macroeconomic modeling, subjective data selection, prediction of policy responses).

The difficulties with the Volcker Rule are compounded beyond Basel III, however, for two reasons. First, the rule has additional, separate benefits, such as the mitigation and reduction of conflicts of interest, which (as with the mutual fund governance rules) can only be quantified by relying on causal inferences with low-powered tools about complex institutional arrangements. Second, and perhaps more important, it remains unclear how, if at all, the Volcker Rule will in fact reduce the risk or cost of financial crises. The Rule’s proponents (including Volcker himself) strongly believe that it will, by decreasing the role of speculation within banks and perhaps by limiting the ability of banks to attract and retain individuals with a risk-taking temperament. 346 But those judgments do not rest on historical data, nor is there any mechanical relationship between an activity (proprietary trading) and failure, as with capital levels. Ironically, then, the primary category of benefits (reduced systemic crisis risk from less speculation by banks) is inherently speculative, as with any novel structural rule or activity ban of a similar kind.

Quantifying the aggregate costs of the rule would be equally difficult. While the OCC quantified a subset of costs, it did not quantify the costs that are likely to be largest—especially the costs of lower liquidity. As the OCC noted, it is possible to quantify those costs: there are research papers estimating the cost of reduced liquidity for specific categories of assets. 347 But, as the OCC also noted, any estimates produced by relating predicted reductions in liquidity to this sparse research literature would be “difficult.” 348 Among other things, a full set of cost estimates would require predicting the impact of the rule on liquidity across a range of financial markets (including anticipating entry by institutions not subject to the rule—institutions that could be expected to take advantage of any competitive opportunities opened up by the exit of banks subject to the rule). Those estimates would then have to be linked to estimates of the impact on the cost of capital from any expected reduction in the liquidity of one channel for capital raising, again taking into account possible substitution effects from other channels. Then, finally, the effects on output of any estimated capital cost increase would have to be quantified, using a macroeconomic model. As with Basel III, the result would be complex, difficult, constrained by limited data, highly contestable, and sensitive to modeling assumptions.

E. “Gold Standard” Examples of CBA/FR

Perhaps other significant regulations—beyond those explored in the case studies presented above—are more susceptible to quantified CBA/FR. Taking a cue from the adversarial legal system, in which neutral judges rely on advocates to advance the best evidence in favor of a cause, this section reviews two regulations that CBA/FR proponents hold up as examples of “gold standard” quantified CBA/FR 349 —the SEC’s cross-border swaps rules and the FSA’s mortgage market reforms—on the theory that they should provide the best evidence that quantified CBA/FR is capable of being done in a reliable, precise way. These rules are also high-profile and indisputably significant, and are of interest for evaluating CBA/FR law because the agencies did conduct and publish CBA/FR in response to CBA/FR law: the SEC was responding to the D.C. Circuit decisions reviewed above, and the FSA was complying with a U.K. statute requiring CBA/FR, precisely the kind of mandate that CBA/FR advocates hope to bring to the U.S.

Does either of those rules demonstrate that quantified CBA/FR is feasible and desirable? Far from it—they instead show how easily CBA/FR can camouflage the effects of rulemaking, rather than discipline it. Both case studies show that even motivated and relatively expert members of the public—specifically, the Center for Capital Market Regulation, composed of leading financial industry participants and staffed by technically trained lawyers and economists—can apparently misread the contents and achievements of a lengthy and technical cost-benefit analysis. The case study of the FSA’s mortgage reforms also illustrates that even the most creative and sustained effort to quantify the costs and benefits of a fairly narrow but important financial regulation remained fragile, imprecise, and incapable of significantly constraining regulatory judgment, by the admission of the staff carrying out the analysis.

1. The SEC’s Cross-Border Rules on Swaps

One of the few examples of CBA/FR of U.S. financial regulatory rules praised by CBA/FR proponents was conducted by the SEC, in its proposed rules on cross-border swaps under the Dodd-Frank Act (the Cross-Border Swap Release). 350 Those rules are designed to fill a regulatory gap 351 relating to over-the-counter (OTC) derivatives markets, which exploded over the past two decades and exacerbated the 2008 financial crisis, causing the insolvency of one of the world’s largest insurance companies (AIG) and triggering a bailout through an unprecedented series of actions by the U.S. Treasury and the Federal Reserve Board. 352

The Dodd-Frank Act authorizes the SEC and the CFTC 353 to register and regulate entities active in the OTC swap markets, 354 and to establish rules for clearing and trade execution, recordkeeping, real-time reporting, and disclosure. Pursuant to this authority, the SEC (in conjunction with the CFTC) has issued two releases defining terms 355 and proposed or adopted ten sets of rules on domestic swap activities. 356 The Dodd-Frank Act was clear that swap regulation should also cover cross-border activity that could affect the U.S. markets. 357 To that end, the SEC proposed a rule in May 2013 to address cross-border swaps comprehensively, issuing one large release collecting, discussing, and analyzing all of the swap-related rules as they would apply to cross-border activities. That release contained roughly 200 pages labeled “economic analysis,” a third of the total release—including both conceptual and limited elements of quantified CBA/FR—and cross-referenced lengthy CBA/FR in previously issued releases. 358 By comparison to CBA/FR in most prior SEC releases, the length of the CBA/FR is indeed impressive, which is part of why CBA/FR advocates praised it. 359 The SEC’s CBA/FR was also praised because it focused on full, quantified CBA/FR, “estimating the quantitative impact of each key aspect of the proposed rule, rather than simply assess[ ing ] firm-specific compliance costs.” 360

However, a careful (if exhausting) review of the CBA/FR in the Cross-Border Swap Release shows that it is comprehensive only in its qualitative economic analysis of the proposed rules and contains little quantified information, other than for a subset of compliance costs. As noted in passing towards the beginning of the CBA/FR, “Many of the resulting costs and benefits are difficult to quantify with any degree of certainty, especially as the practices of market participants are expected to evolve and adapt to changes in technology and market developments.” 361 The SEC divides its CBA/FR into “assessment” costs—the costs of determining if a given entity is subject to swap regulation, a subset of compliance costs—and “programmatic” costs and benefits due to subjecting swaps to regulation. 362 The primary programmatic benefits the SEC identified were promoting competition by increasing market access and transparency, reducing search costs, and increasing price efficiency. 363 The primary programmatic costs the SEC identified were reduced liquidity and depth in the swap markets due to market participants’ withdrawing because transparency requirements will reveal valuable information, and a potentially increased incentive to “race to the bottom” as participants relocate cross-border operations to jurisdictions with less regulation. 364

Almost no information relating to “programmatic” costs and benefits is quantified. No models of competition, liquidity, or prices under the rules are presented. Instead, the SEC repeatedly said that it lacks data and/or an inferential basis for quantifying those costs and benefits. Exceptions include, for example, a quantification of the costs of building a compliant swap execution facility from scratch and maintaining it thereafter or modifying an existing trading platform into compliance and maintaining it. 365 But these exceptions prove only the general absence of quantification, as they relate to a subset of the costs of a subset of the rules proposed in the release—a subset of a subset of a subset of what a full quantified CBA/FR would include.

This description is not meant to criticize the absence of quantification. The SEC’s decision not to quantify is fully justified, given the state of available information and research methods. The Dodd-Frank Act effectively required the creation of entirely new OTC swaps markets. Private actors will be reacting to these novel regulations in ways that cannot be reliably predicted. The realization of the rules’ major potential benefit—increased competition—depends upon latent demand for products (transparently cleared swaps). Private actors had only limited incentives to provide these products under prior rules and the value of the products will be altered by other new aspects of the rules, such as segregation and capital requirements . The realization of the rules’ major potential cost—reduced liquidity and depth relative to prior markets—will also be a function of latent demand. The size of the cost will also turn on the importance of proprietary information that may be revealed in more transparent markets. Another major potential cost—an increased incentive for participants to relocate to other jurisdictions—depends on political and policy outcomes in other countries, as well as the ability of international regulatory coordination to cope with or blunt those incentives.

Although justified in this respect, the SEC’s CBA/FR nevertheless must be fairly viewed as conceptual, not quantified. Rather than showing quantification is possible and desirable, as a matter of policy or law, the Cross-Border Swap Release shows just the opposite. Yet CBA/FR advocates have singled out the Cross-Border Swap Release for accomplishing something it did not accomplish. 366 How could that be? Perhaps the praise was false, a mere rhetorical pretense in service of the political goal of promoting CBA/FR.

But a more charitable possibility exists: perhaps CBA/FR advocates did not see through the camouflage of the SEC’s release. As noted, the CBA/FR is 200 pages long and incorporates lengthier CBA/FR sections in other related releases. It is turgid, vague, and full of jargon. Discussions of less important assessment costs are longer than discussions of more important programmatic costs and benefits. Specific quantified amounts appear regularly, 367 so someone skimming the analysis might surmise that it was filled with quantitative analysis, while in fact the vast majority of the amounts relate to assessment costs or a small subset of programmatic costs, not to programmatic benefits or the most important programmatic costs. 368 The release contains lengthy discussions of qualitative costs and benefits of a de minimis exemption from coverage by the rules, while nowhere setting forth a detailed conceptual outline of how one might (in theory) measure the costs and benefits of being covered by the rules. Important points relevant to the limited quantification in the release are buried in footnotes, 369 while whole pages are taken up with text such as this:

Segregation requirements would limit the potential losses for security-based swap customers if a registered security-based swap dealer fails. The extent to which assets are in fact protected by proposed Rule 18a-4(a)-(d) would depend on how effective they are in practice in allowing assets to be readily returned to customers. In the cross-border context, the effectiveness of the segregation requirement with respect to foreign security-based swap dealers in practice may depend on many factors, including the type and objective of the insolvency or liquidation proceeding and how the U.S. Bankruptcy Code, SIPA, banking regulations, and applicable foreign insolvency laws are interpreted by the U.S. bankruptcy court, SIPC, Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation, and relevant foreign authorities. In the Capital, Margin, and Segregation Proposing Release, we stated that it would be difficult to measure the benefits of the segregation requirements proposed by the Commission under Section 3E of the Exchange Act; however, we believe that Rule 15c3-3, the existing segregation rule for broker-dealers, would provide a reasonable template for crafting the segregation requirements for security-based swap dealers. The ensuing increased confidence of market participants when transacting in security-based swaps, as compared to the OTC derivatives market as it exists today, should increase the desire to trade security-based swaps and generally benefit market participants. 370

Perhaps someone finds this and similar paragraphs illuminating. I do not. Did including it in a 200-page section labeled “economic analysis” in a 650-page release inform the public about the costs and benefits of requiring dealers in cross-border swaps to segregate customer assets? In what way is it “economic” analysis, as distinct from the more general form of analysis that has long been included in adopting releases? The paragraph would look out of place in an economics journal. Even if these 210 words were boiled down to a more succinct, social-scientific style, 371 would a law requiring such a statement discipline the SEC, improve the public’s ability to comment on the proposals, or correct the SEC’s potential cognitive biases? I cannot see how.

Again, I do not intend to criticize the authors of the Cross-Border Swap Release; to the contrary, I commend them. They accomplished an important goal—eliciting praise from a group of critics of the SEC’s CBA practices—and likely helped set up the SEC to defend itself against any court challenges to its rules. The staff accomplished here what any rational actor at a regulatory agency would want to accomplish given the court decisions reviewed in Part II above—decisions that have created a strong incentive for regulators to generate precisely the kind of qualitative, lengthy, and largely opaque “gold standard” CBA/FR included in the Cross-Border Swap Release.

2. The FSA’s Mortgage Market Reforms

A second example held up as model CBA/FR is the set of mortgage market rules passed by the FSA in 2011. The FSA was abolished in 2010 (effective in 2013) for its failures to foresee, prevent, and mitigate the 2008 crisis. 372 Among its pre-crisis failures was allowing significant amounts of mortgage loans to be made to borrowers who could not repay the loans other than by refinancing or reselling their homes into what optimists hoped would be an ever-rising market. 373 Reforms adopted in 2011 require lenders to assess affordability of homes before lending to buyers, to include the possibility of interest rate increases in making those affordability assessments, and to evaluate interest-only mortgages without assuming (as opposed to demonstrating) the possibility of a refinancing. 374

a. The FSA’s CBA/FR

Since 2000, UK law has required the FSA to publish a CBA/FR of its regulations and guidance, 375 such as the mortgage reforms. That 131-page CBA/FR was attached as an annex to the reform proposal (a “consultation paper” in European legal jargon). 376 In it, the FSA summarized the benefit of the main reform (mandatory affordability analysis) as protecting some borrowers “from mortgage impairment,” and its cost as “prevent[ ing ] [other borrowers] from taking out the mortgage they want.” 377

In an effort to quantify and compare those primary benefits and costs, the FSA used a multistep process. First, it applied a multivariate logistic model to a large ( n =730,000) sample of loans from 2005 to 2010 to estimate the probability of loan “impairment.” 378 It then used ordinary-least-squares regression of the probability of impairment on factors it selected as contributing to impairment to quantify the contribution each factor made to impairment risk. 379 It used “judgment” to choose factors relevant to loan underwriting to identify a cut-off where impairment risk increased “markedly,” 380 on the theory that this was where the new affordability requirement would have affected sample loans. 381

With those models, the FSA concluded that the rules would have prevented roughly 200,000 loans from entering default (“unaffordable” loans), and constrained approximately 530,000 borrowers to take out smaller or delayed loans than they could have taken out and repaid without the rules. 382 The FSA then assumed the rules would prevent similar future defaults, which the FSA assumed would create solely social costs and so counted solely as benefits of the rules. 383 The FSA further assumed the rules would generate social costs but no benefits if they prevented or delayed borrowers who could have afforded larger or earlier loans from obtaining consumption benefits. 384

To quantify a comparison between these direct costs and benefits of the new rules on borrowers, the FSA needed a common metric. Because the FSA had no data on actual demand for loans in a hypothetical world without information asymmetries (a market failure addressed by the rules), 385 it estimated effects not on welfare but on psychological “well-being,” for which it had proxy data, derived from a U.K. government household panel survey with data from 1991 to 2008. 386 By regressing self-reported well-being scores on “housing-related events” in a fixed-effects regression with other controls from the survey, the FSA generated parameters 387 for changes in well-being for events that were (by assumption) related to unaffordable loans (for example, payment problems) or affordable loans (for example, becoming a home owner rather than a renter, moving into a larger home). The FSA found that effects on well-being were “much greater” for payment problems and defaults than for foregone improvements in housing, 388 such that the net effects on all affected borrowers were positive overall, despite being expected to stop more affordable loans than unaffordable loans. 389

While this procedure allowed for a comparison of direct effects of the rule, by design it did not monetize the effects for use in a full, quantified CBA. To do that, self-reported well-being figures needed to be converted to pounds, to compare to other costs and benefits. Nevertheless, the FSA exploited the happenstance that the effects on well-being of loans’ falling into arrears were similar in size to the effects of a person’s becoming unemployed, a condition more easily monetized by reference to income data. 390 The bottom line was an average benefit of £ 350 per borrower over the period 2005 to 2010. 391 Added to this was an additional benefit of ten pounds per borrower in the form of fees and repossession costs that the rules would have prevented. 392

Finally, the FSA estimated compliance costs for the new rules at between 47 and 170 million pounds per year, for an average of £ 109 million per year, based on a combination of its own survey of lenders, input from a consulting group ( Oxera ) that conducted its own surveys, and internal FSA data. 393 Using the FSA’s discount rate of 3.5%, 394 one can derive a present value of compliance costs of between £ 1.3 and £ 4.9 billion. The FSA did not explain how it was able to relate the per-borrower benefits it estimated from its main analyses to the per-year compliance costs it estimated. However, it did present a per-borrower compliance cost ( £ 120 per borrower), which can be related to its aggregate average compliance cost estimate ( £ 109 million per year), to derive a per-year benefit from the earlier analyses of £ 300 million per year. Using the FSA’s 3.5% discount rate, that annual amount has a present value of nine billion pounds. The bottom line implicit in the FSA’s analysis, then, is a total benefit (net of compliance costs) of six billion pounds.

Separately, the FSA used a macroeconomic (“ NiGEM ”) 395 model to estimate effects of the rules on output. With many assumptions, 396 the model predicted six categories of sequential monetary impacts. 397 The long-run effects in the sixth category—increased output from increased business investment—more than outweighed categories (such as reduced home lending, home prices, and household consumption) that would reduce output in the short run. The net effect was estimated at over £ 300 million more per year of output. 398 Using the FSA’s discount rate of 3.5%, the present value of this increase would be nine billion pounds, 399 as much as the total direct benefits. Yet elsewhere, without explanation or detail, the CBA/FR stated it had not included output in its bottom-line summary of costs and benefits because “the margin of error inherent in the estimation of the macroeconomic impacts means that in reality this impact could either be positive or negative.” 400

b. Assessing the FSA’s CBA/FR

Any assessment of the FSA’s CBA/FR should begin by acknowledging it is better as an academic exercise—more complex, detailed, and creative—than anything yet produced by any U.S. financial regulatory agency. It relies on academic working papers, several different datasets, and multiple modeling techniques, and tackles a host of difficult estimation problems. It actually attempts to quantify the benefits of a financial regulation—something that the rest of Part III shows is rarely done. If CBA/FR has a role to play in the United States, the FSA’s CBA/FR is a useful example of a path forward, just as CBA/FR advocates suggest by calling it the “gold standard.”

However, it should also be recognized that the FSA’s job here was by many measures easier than that faced in other regulatory contexts. The mortgage reforms were important and will have complex effects, but their importance and complexity pale beside those of more general regulations such as Basel III or the Volcker Rule. The mortgage reforms impose relatively light mandates on the process and terms of one class of consumer financial product—an important class, to be sure—but one that is considerably simpler than, for example, swaps or even common stock issued by a variety of public companies with a variety of governance arrangements and disclosure practices. A home mortgage is a loan, with clear and definite terms, and a limited set of straightforward purposes. Other important transactions have similar characteristics—consumer loans, credit card loans, student loans—and regulations of those markets are also likely to be more tractable for CBA/FR than the more complex regulations reviewed here. 401

Despite being in a simpler regulatory context, a review of the FSA’s CBA/FR of its mortgage reforms nevertheless shows how fragile and unreliable the analysis remains, and how susceptible such CBA/FR is to being used as camouflage, rather than as discipline—particularly as it gets more complex and ambitious (as it will have to do to approach the goals that its advocates have for it). Below is a short list of weaknesses in the FSA’s CBA/FR that illustrate both its shortcomings and how it could just as easily mislead as inform the public.

First, the FSA is clear in its exposition that it used judgment in a number of crucial places. Examples include: (1) it created its own loan impairment model, where its staff effectively chose their own underwriting criteria, rather than relying on industry models, due to data limitations; (2) it chose where the new rules would begin to bind on lending decisions, using visual inspection of a figure rather than more quantitative methods; and (3) it chose how to “weight” the well-being results given the multiple comparisons it had with its data. Another important judgment the FSA made was to ignore the output of its macroeconomic modeling, as noted above, despite the fact that the net benefits on output of the rules were comparable to the direct benefits to borrowers. Each of these decisions, while defensible, required judgment.

Second, the FSA’s entire well-being analysis, which is its core method for estimating the effects of the rules, was usable only because of the happenstance that its output could be related to unemployment data. If the net effect on well-being had been significantly larger or smaller, this method would have been unavailable, and the FSA would have had to use another method to monetize the well-being effects, something that is—as the FSA noted—“notoriously problematic.” 402 This difficulty calls into question the viability of this “gold standard” CBA as a model for the future.

Third, the FSA made a number of assumptions that affected its CBA: (a) it assumed that loans would not be made if they were reduced by thirty percent in size (an arbitrary figure) due to the new rules, but would be made otherwise; 403 (b) it assumed that delayed loans would never be made; 404 (c) it assumed that repossession had no effects on well-being distinct from default, because it had too few observations in its well-being dataset to estimate a different effect; 405 (d) by using a fixed effects model to generate causal inferences about loan rules and well-being, it assumed that unobserved variation in individual respondents does not co-vary with home-related events; 406 (e) it assumed that data from 2006 to 2011—a period of concededly low and falling interest rates—predicts future home market conditions; 407 (f) it implicitly assumed that its modeling of the effects of Basel III were correct, but as discussed in Part III.C above, that is a fragile assumption; (g) it estimated compliance costs from a small survey ( n =15, response rate 60%) of firms that would be subject to the new rules, resulting in potentially biased data; 408 and (h) it assumed that the social cost of transfers represented by repossessions and resales of repossessed homes (as opposed to the transaction costs of those events, which it did estimate) was zero. 409 Each of these assumptions is defensible as a matter of regulatory discretion, as each simplified the analysis or coped with data limits. Together, however, they demonstrate the lack of reliability or precision in the overall analysis.

Two other strong assumptions are nowhere discussed or explained in detail: that all “unaffordable” loans would produce only social losses, and that all “affordable” loans would produce only social gains. Both assumptions seem dubious. Some loans that turn out to be unaffordable represent gambles by borrowers that turn out badly, but which, ex ante, even on a fully informed basis, the borrowers would take again. The new rules will likely prevent those gambles, and while one can make good arguments in favor of preventing such gambling, at least some normative approaches to welfare analysis would treat preventing informed consumers from making knowing gambles as a welfare harm. Some loans on which borrowers never default are nevertheless the product of avoidable misunderstandings by borrowers, and others are the product of deception and fraud by lenders: the fact that a borrower chooses not to default on such a loan does not imply that the borrower would take it out again, were the borrower adequately evaluated and warned about the loan’s potential risks. Indeed, the FSA’s own data showed that many non-defaulting borrowers experienced high levels of stress and difficulty in making payments, suggesting that they may regret their loans. The new rules will likely reduce some of those loans, but none of the associated increase in well-being was counted in the FSA’s analysis. Nowhere does the FSA identify these possibilities in a clear manner, and the technical language in which it presents its well-being analysis may prevent many readers from even understanding the assumptions that have been made, much less appreciate what effect they have on the bottom line.

Finally, despite the relative merits of the substance, the FSA’s presentation is not a model of clarity or candor in other respects. The assumptions listed in the two paragraphs above are not collected in one place in the FSA’s paper, but are mentioned in scattered locations, or are not explicitly noted at all. The sensitivity of the bottom-line results of the CBA/FR to important assumptions is not made clear. 410 For example, the FSA does show that parts of its analysis are sensitive to assumptions about future levels of lending activity. It does so by breaking its historical data into two sub-periods: the “boom” period of the 2000s, when the new rules would have affected between 1.7% and 10.5% of borrowers, and the “subdued” period after the collapse, when they would have affected no more than 0.4% of borrowers. 411 Similarly, the FSA shows that in the subdued period, seven percent of borrowers who would have been affected by the reforms faced actual impairment in its historical data, while thirty percent would have faced impairments in the boom period. 412 The FSA does not, however, translate this sensitivity into bottom-line effects on benefits (gross or net). It does not present sensitivities to most of the assumptions discussed in the prior two paragraphs, and because it does not translate per-borrower benefits from its well-being analysis into present values, it does not allow readers to compare those benefits with the possible range of macroeconomic effects of the rules.

In sum, it is not clear that this “gold standard” CBA/FR, while distinctly more ambitious and interesting than other examples of CBA/FR, was a net benefit to an assessment of the mortgage rules. The FSA’s analysis is thought-provoking and may represent a step on a path toward regulatory capacity to use CBA/FR to generate outputs that can help the public assess the value of regulations such as the mortgage rules. Nevertheless, the bottom line of the FSA’s CBA/FR depends on assumptions and limited data to such an extent that, with equally plausible assumptions or different data, it could have come out with a different sign or order of magnitude attached to it. The FSA does include a number of disclaimers precisely to this effect—writing that “certain data, for example on relevant households’ expenditure, are not available . . . [such that] this CBA has been unusually difficult to prepare [and led to a] wide margin of uncertainty around its results.” 413 Elsewhere, the FSA notes that the analysis “is inherently highly uncertain,” with the result that “[ t]o a significant extent . . . the decision on whether to proceed with the proposed rules has to be based on social and political judgments.” 414 And further: “It is extremely difficult to identify exactly how the responsible lending requirements will change borrowing in the market or the likely scale of this. It requires some judgemental assumptions on the basis of imperfect evidence.” 415 None of this would be apparent to anyone reading U.S. white papers advocating CBA/FR legal reform. 416 Therefore, the FSA’s CBA of its mortgage rules came with some unquantifiable cost in increasing misunderstandings of what CBA/FR is capable of, while failing to improve the public’s ability to evaluate the merits of the rules or achieving any other obvious benefit. It is an example of why quantified CBA/FR should not be mandated, rather than an example of why it should be.

F. Summary of Case Studies

The substantive rules reviewed in the foregoing case studies are summarized in Table 4.

summary of case studies

As reflected in Table 4, the case studies range across representative regulatory instruments 417 : disclosure (SOX 404), governance (mutual fund rules), capital regulation (Basel III), and activity limits (Volcker Rule). The cross-border swaps rules cover a large number of regulatory instruments, including disclosure and capital requirements, but also rules requiring segregation , risk management , margin limits , and fair dealing . The mortgage reforms represent a final, important category of financial regulation—consumer protection, in the form of required process and constraints on contract terms . The rules’ benefits range across public goods pursued by financial regulation: more competition, fewer systemic crises and harmful conflicts of interest, and reduced levels of asymmetric information. 418

challenges for possible or actual efforts at guesstimated cba / fr in case studies

Table 5 summarizes the conclusions of the case studies on the feasibility of quantitative CBA/FR. As can be seen, it shows that any substantial financial regulatory rules will face one or more of five serious challenges: (1) data limitations, (2) causal inference challenges, (3) the need to incorporate judgmental macroeconomic models, (4) the need to incorporate even more judgmental policy/political models, and (5) the need to make contestable, judgmental assumptions or modeling choices that have large effects on the outputs of the analysis. Not every challenge is as acute for every kind of rule—political/policy modeling is probably not a first-order component of an analysis of an anti-fraud or governance rule, for example. But all rules face data challenges and are highly sensitive to assumptions; all face causal inference challenges more severe in kind than the ones faced in many non-financial contexts (as discussed more in Part IV); and most require the analyst to embed (explicitly or not) a macroeconomic model of the same judgmental nature as that used in setting monetary policy.

The central conclusion of the case studies is that quantitative CBA/FR is not currently feasible with any degree of precision and reliability for representative types of financial regulation. Anything presented as quantified CBA/FR is in fact judgmental in nature, not an actual alternative to judgment but rather its equivalent in numerical form—“judgment in disguise.” Such quantitative CBA/FR as has been done is better understood as “guesstimated,” and has been presented without clear disclaimers and sensitivity analyses. As a result, it is more likely to mislead and camouflage than inform or discipline. The only kind of CBA that is currently feasible for representative types of financial regulation is conceptual CBA, augmented by limited elements of quantified evidence that will be more illustrative than disciplinary.

IV. what are the implications of these case studies?

The case studies in Part III suggest that the capacity of anyone—including financial regulatory agencies, OIRA, academic researchers, CBA/FR proponents, litigators, and courts—to conduct quantified CBA/FR with any real precision or confidence does not exist for important, representative types of financial regulation. This Part discusses the reasons for and implications of this conclusion.

A. Why Is Quantified CBA/FR So Unreliable?

A straightforward implication of the case studies is that efforts by the financial agencies at quantified CBA/FR will for the foreseeable future produce only guesstimation . Back-of-the-envelope guesses at ranges of magnitudes are currently feasible, but precise and reliable estimates are not. Too many variables are in play for any given rule, and too many contestable assumptions are required, for anyone producing or consuming guesstimated CBA/FR to have any confidence in any specific estimate of costs or benefits, even if expressed in ranges or bounds. 419 While guesstimated CBA/FR can draw on social scientific disciplines, such as financial economics, and while the agencies themselves may reasonably attempt quantified CBA/FR on occasion as a way of helping analysts better understand the implications of a given regulation, quantified CBA/FR will not be replicable, reliable, or predictive.

CBA/FR should be understood not as science but as number-laden guesswork, and should be treated as such by the public, regulators, and courts. While guesstimation can be a legitimate part of decision making, as one input into a judgmental choice, it should not “guide” policy except in the loosest sense. Basing policy on specific quantitative outputs would simply be a poor exercise of judgment.

This conclusion—that quantitative CBA is not a good basis for setting policy—may contrast with practice in other regulatory domains, where quantitative CBA appears to be used in setting policy. 420 Possibly the conclusions generated by these case studies might be generalizable to some non-financial domains. But it is worth considering whether there are features of CBA/FR that make it more difficult to perform effectively than CBA in other domains, at least when considering “typical” financial and non-financial regulations. While this topic warrants considerably more analysis than is provided in this Article, here are three tentative explanations for why CBA/FR is so hard, with the recognition that some of what follows may also characterize some non-financial domains, at least in part. 421

1. Finance Is Central to the Economy

Part of the explanation for how far we are from reliable and precise quantified CBA/FR estimates is that finance is at the heart of the economy. Any change in regulation with a material impact on finance will have a material impact on the economy, and large and complex effects on welfare. Recall from Part III.E.2 that the FSA’s mortgage reforms—relatively simple consumer protection regulations on the surface—were conceptually identified as having multiple, complex effects on the macroeconomy . 422 They would cut home lending, lower home prices, reduce consumer spending, increase consumer saving, reduce consumer borrowing, and increase business lending and investment. The FSA used one of a large family of materially different but respectable macroeconomic models to derive a positive net effect of $9 billion, which it then claimed it was ignoring as too unreliable. Many rules would have more complex effects.

Macroeconomic models that include finance are still highly contested. They are the stuff of newspaper op-eds and blogs as much as consensus models in academic journals. 423 The ripple effects of financial regulation are too large and complex, relative to its direct effects, to allow for reliable predictions of net effects. As noted in Part I.D, this reason explains why even CBA proponents concede that monetary policy should remain unregulated by CBA laws. What advocates have not grasped, but Part III shows, is that important financial regulation is always likely to interact with the economy—perhaps not to the same extent as quantitative easing, but with enough impact to generate large (and uncertain) effects on economic growth.

By contrast, consider the Department of Transportation’s proposed rule to increase rear visibility in motor vehicles. 424 While there were uncertainties associated with estimating the rule’s benefits—owing to the question of whether to value children differently than adults—and the costs—owing to the possibility that compliance costs might fall over time and to the appropriate discount rate to use in estimating future costs—estimating neither costs nor benefits required a macroeconomic model. 425 Indeed, it is hard to imagine a financial regulation important enough to warrant significant CBA/FR costs that would be as simple to model as this rule. Yet this rule is typical of many non-financial regulations, which generate direct compliance costs and result in straightforward improvements in safety, with few knock-on systemic effects.

2. Finance Is Social and Political

A second reason why quantitative CBA/FR is hard is that the main units of variation and change in finance are not things, or even individuals, but groups of people—groups with not only economic but also social and political relations. Finance is about firms, corporations—groups of people coming together to form and fund a business—and financial markets—groups of people routinely trading intangibles. These features of finance can be contrasted with some non-financial domains, where objects of regulation are inanimate (for example, chemicals, rear-facing car cameras) and regulations are designed to achieve relatively simple ends (for example, changing the frequency and intensity of the use of identified chemicals, or requiring installation of cameras). While a chemical can interact with the environment in ways that are challenging to model and predict, those interactions are generally simpler than interactions of groups of humans. Every human possesses agency and interacts with others in non-linear, unpredictable ways. As stated by one theoretical physicist, “Computational approaches [to modeling] have been very useful in physics because the knowledge of microscopic laws constrains theoretical modeling in extremely controlled ways. This is almost never possible for socioeconomic systems.” 426

Chemicals can also be subjected easily to randomly controlled experiments, but experiments are more difficult for humans and are frequently not feasible for groups. Because finance affects the economy, modeling policy also becomes necessary to quantify effects of financial regulation; finance is more routinely and powerfully political than chemistry. Part of evaluating the costs of a crisis, as Part III showed, requires predicting how governments will respond. No similar efforts are required for most typical non-financial regulations. 427

3. Finance Is Non-Stationary

A third reason that may help explain why quantified CBA/FR is hard is that underlying regularities that enable quantification are commonly “non-stationary” in finance—more likely to change over time than in other domains. The proverbial “rocket science,” for example, uses relatively simple models of inert objects moving through space, with key inputs—such as the gravitational constant and gravitational acceleration 428 —that do not change. 429 By contrast, most relationships in finance change through time, often rapidly. Consider the striking decline from 1978 to 1999 in the dividend payout ratio or the steady fall since 1930 in the ratio of directly to institutionally invested stocks in U.S. retail portfolios, both changes with large implications for the costs and benefits of many financial regulations. 430

One reason for the greater degree of non- stationarity in finance is that finance is non-physical, such that technology shocks have larger and more unpredictable effects on optimal financial choices. This point is reflected in the case studies in Part III: new technologies of derivatives and securitization were significant causes of the last crisis, 431 which gave rise to several of the rules reviewed. While technological progress affects all regulatory domains, physics, chemistry, and biology are more central to non-financial regulation than to financial regulation, and regularities uncovered in those disciplines have proven more durable than those found in finance. As summarized by the same physicist quoted above:

Nature has been there since ever, but it has taken centuries to develop a reasonable understanding of little parts of it. Many of the things which are traded nowadays in financial markets did not exist few decades ago, not to speak of internet communities. In addition, we face a situation in which the density and range of interactions are steadily increasing, thus making theoretical concepts based on effective non-interacting theories inadequate. 432

No doubt there are other explanations for why quantitative CBA/FR is so unreliable; some have to do with historical unwillingness of the financial agencies to invest sufficiently in the task. No doubt, too, there are areas of non-financial regulation in which science is weak, and CBA there, too, cannot be reliably used as a strong guide for regulation. But the problems in financial regulation are real and likely to persist for the foreseeable future.

B. New CBA/FR Mandates Should Be Passed Only If CBA/FR Satisfies CBA

A second implication of the case studies in Part III is that new legal mandates for CBA/FR such as those reviewed in Part II are a bad idea, at least until CBA/FR can be shown to pass its own test—that is, to be likely to result in benefits that outweigh its costs. It is hard to understand how any CBA advocate could argue to the contrary. Instead, CBA/FR should be conducted only to the extent and in the manner the expert agencies choose, since they are in the best position to decide whether CBA/FR will be, in a given instance, likely to pass its own test. This conclusion is particularly true when it comes to quantified CBA, because of how unreliable quantified CBA/FR remains. CBA/FR law’s purpose—to discipline agencies and reduce agency costs—will not be furthered by forcing analyses that amount to no more than guesstimation and camouflage—again, “judgment in disguise.”

Conceptually, what would the benefits of CBA/FR be, given the conclusion of Part III? If CBA/FR were precise and reliable, it might generate the benefits of disciplining agencies, informing the public through increased transparency, and counteracting cognitive biases faced by the agencies. But CBA/FR’s benefits have been low, and are likely to remain low, for the reasons sketched in Part IV.A above: CBA/FR is by definition about finance—and finance is at the heart of the economy; is social and political; and is composed of non-stationary relationships that exhibit secular change. These features undermine the ability of science to precisely and reliably estimate the effects of financial regulations, even retrospectively. Whenever agencies face such sensitive and speculative forecasting abilities, quantified CBA is not capable of disciplining regulatory analysis, and it will generate low benefits.

The analysis is even worse for CBA/FR mandates when one focuses not only on the abstract benefits they might create but also on the marginal benefits they might create—over the baseline of the status quo. Other constraints—the general goals of the agencies, the screening and socialization of the agency staff, and the political oversight of the agencies by Congress, through confirmations, budgets, hearings, and public criticism of the sort reviewed in Part II—will prevent new regulation or deregulation that is so extreme in generating costs without offsetting benefits that it could not be justified by the current art of guesstimated CBA. Within the range of plausible regulatory action set by those other constraints, the financial agencies retain too much discretion to select inputs and make assumptions in CBA/FR, meaning that numbers that emerge in any effort at quantification are unlikely to demonstrate whether a proposed change is net beneficial. Worse, the goal of disciplining agencies may be undermined if the result is to encourage agencies to use CBA/FR as camouflage—to hide discretionary judgments under impressive numbers.

As discussed more in Part IV.D below, CBA/FR remains a useful conceptual framework, quantified CBA/FR is a worthy long-term research goal, and attempts to quantify may advance the research needed to achieve reliable, precise estimates, making it a worthwhile project for agencies to pursue, in parallel with their other activities. 433 But the current benefits of CBA/FR remain low, because its real effects remain far off in time; like any regulatory benefit, the benefits of these real effects should be discounted to present value. Moreover, CBA/FR will produce costs—resources consumed, regulatory delay, diffusion of regulatory focus, and potential decreases in regulatory transparency—particularly if regulatory agencies and any courts involved in reviewing agency action do not have good incentives to be honest about the limits and uncertainties of the results.

Empowering courts to review even conceptual CBA/FR policy analysis is likely to be a bad idea. Judicial review is not likely to generate any significant improvement in CBA/FR itself, as agencies will likely respond to the threat of such review by hiding, not exposing, the weaknesses in their analyses. Nothing produced by the back-and-forth between the SEC and the D.C. Circuit over the mutual fund rules reviewed in Parts II and III meaningfully advanced public understanding of the qualitative costs and benefits of requiring more independent fund boards; the compliance costs on which the Chamber of Commerce court focused were minor even by the lights of the Chamber of Commerce itself. 434 The SEC’s cross-border swap CBA, reviewed in Part III.E, provides a clear picture of how little the threat of such review will accomplish, relative to what conceptual CBA voluntarily presented by an agency might do.

Mandating an open interagency process for CBA—such as requiring a financial agency to publish not only its CBA but also the views of OIRA on its CBA—will also worsen outcomes. 435 The result will be a bigger record that will continue to be largely ignored by the public but used by litigators to pick at particular agency judgments as arbitrary and capricious under the APA. The benefits such a mandate might achieve can already be achieved if the financial agency sees the process as valuable, as evidenced by the voluntary cooperation between the CFTC and OIRA during the Dodd-Frank Act rollout. 436 The cases reviewed in Part II show how aggressive some D.C. Circuit panels have been in using such review to overturn agency actions, particularly when an agency’s commissioners have been divided in making any regulatory change. Trebling the number of pages or components of CBA available for judicial second-guessing, and adding the possibility of interagency disagreement to the mix, will incite more interventions, with no clear benefit to anyone other than litigators. 437

More extensive judicial review will have other pernicious consequences. Not only will agencies rationally use CBA/FR as camouflage, but they can also be expected to go to Congress to lobby for the establishment of rules through detailed congressional mandates, which will likely receive greater deference from courts than rules adopted pursuant to congressional delegations of discretion to achieve general goals. 438 Both the litigation and the shift towards congressional mandates will produce a general slowdown, not just of regulation, but also of deregulation and regulatory reform, and will likely increase partisan polarization in and deterioration of public opinion of the very courts charged with that review.

The CBA of CBA just sketched is preliminary and incomplete. Completing a CBA of CBA would require evidence: quantitative studies of the degree to which CBA results in better regulations and more transparency in the regulatory process, as well as quantified estimates of the costs—delay, confusion, camouflage, partisanship—that CBA can introduce. Until evidence is developed to illuminate when CBA/FR passes its own test, we must rely on judgment, just as agencies must when they regulate. As currently informed by the poor results of judicially reviewed CBA/FR (discussed in Part II), it is hard to see how laws that give courts a greater role in second-guessing the choice of when to conduct CBA/FR, or the details of CBA/FR when it is used, could be judged a good idea. 439

C. Existing CBA/FR Laws Are Little Better in Practice

A final implication of Part III is that existing interpretations of the APA and the financial agencies’ governing statutes should be restored to their state prior to Chamber of Commerce , to reduce the influence of concentrated interests through litigation and of politically partisan but unaccountable judges on regulatory outcomes. As shown in Part II, the D.C. Circuit’s new interpretations of the APA have permitted (some) panels to overturn regulatory changes on the ground that a court would conduct its guesstimated CBA differently than an agency’s guesstimated CBA/FR. As shown in Part III, the state of CBA/FR is such that one can reasonably argue that all guesstimated CBA/FR of major financial regulations inevitably will contain multiple arbitrary assumptions and judgments simply in order to allow for rough guesstimates to be made. A legal system that simultaneously requires arbitrary judgments by agencies, and then allows them to be overturned by a court for being arbitrary, depending on which panel of the D.C. Circuit is randomly (that is, arbitrarily) chosen, is self-evidently indefensible. 440

Even if one agrees with a given court that a given rule represents bad policy (as I do with respect to the fund governance rules reviewed in Part III.B), better means exist for those affected by such rules to protect their interests, such as through the legislative process or by developing regulatory proposals to await a new set of regulators—who, after all, are more frequently replaced by politically accountable Presidents than are the judges on the D.C. Circuit. In sum, the current, erratically applied law of CBA/FR raises agency costs as between citizens and their political agents, rather than lowering them as CBA/FR is supposed to accomplish.

Often, the current state of the law on CBA/FR of financial regulation is perceived in simple partisan terms—Republican judges will strike down regulations adopted by regulators appointed by a Democratic President—and this is viewed as good by Republicans (and financial institutions) and bad by Democrats (and individual investors and bank customers). But in a few years the same unfortunate dynamic may reverse, with Democratic judges striking down deregulatory changes adopted by regulators appointed by a Republican President. Regardless of the current state of partisan power sharing, or of one’s political inclinations, it should require more theory and evidence than CBA/FR proponents have developed to leave financial regulation wrapped in the unlovely arms of litigators and the partisan lottery that is the D.C. Circuit. 441

To remedy the situation, two recommendations made by Kraus and Raso for the SEC 442 should be extended to all financial agencies. First, an exemption from the “sunshine” laws 443 should be added to permit closed-door, pre-decisional discussions of CBA/FR among financial agency commissioners, between commissioners and the economic staffs of the agencies, among the agencies, and between the staffs of the agencies and the staffs of OIRA and the OFR. Until CBA/FR is considerably more developed, such deliberations are best conducted in a setting that encourages candor and creativity, rather than defensive camouflage and obfuscation in anticipation of litigation or requests under the Freedom of Information Act. 444 Such a reform would likely increase the willingness of agencies to comply with existing requirements under the CBA Executive Orders 445 that they submit CBA of their annual regulatory agendas to OIRA, requirements that have long been given short shrift by the financial agencies. 446

Second, a “safe harbor” for CBA/FR should be added to the APA and the financial agencies’ governing statutes. The safe harbor can be modeled on the CRA, 447 which courts have interpreted as barring judicial review of agency compliance with the statute, including agency determinations of whether a rule is “major.” As Kraus and Raso put it, “private litigants must not be allowed to throw [CBA/FR] back at the agency as ‘party admissions against interest,’ undermining the validity of the very rules that the analysis informed.” 448 Anyone genuinely interested in fostering CBA/FR should recognize that, with the current, politicized D.C. Circuit only likely to become more polarized after the elimination of the filibuster, the absence of such a safe harbor may well lead agencies to be overly cautious, long-winded, and opaque in their CBA/FR—lawyerly virtues, not economic ones.

D. CBA/FR Remains a Potentially Valuable Component of Policy Analysis

A naïve response to the case studies in Part III would be to jettison CBA/FR altogether. If CBA cannot generate reliable, precise estimates of costs and benefits, one might conclude that it has no value, even as a discretionary component for policymaking. If CBA/FR cannot produce reliable quantification, then it has only costs and no benefits. This response would be a mistake for four reasons. First, it is possible that some financial regulations are susceptible of quantified CBA/FR. There may be some relatively simple financial regulations in which the costs and benefits will be more straightforward to estimate reliably, particularly if the regulations are implemented in a careful way and combined with a retrospective CBA/FR. The case studies in Part III are only a sampling of rules.

Second, conceptual CBA/FR remains the best available overarching framework for organizing and communicating the pros and cons of a proposed regulation. Conceptual CBA/FR is a commonsense way to begin the analysis necessary to evaluate a proposed rule by comparing it to the status quo and plausible alternatives. Indeed, it is hard to imagine conducting any sort of policy analysis without at least engaging in tacit conceptual CBA/FR. Organizing analysis in a conceptual CBA framework will provide some benefit for public understanding, even if the benefit is modest, and even if the negative effects of guesstimated camouflage can easily overwhelm that benefit.

Third, CBA may have effects other than the conventional set outlined in Part I.C (discipline, transparency, and camouflage). CBA guidelines, such as those in the OMB Guidance, 449 also serve a brainstorming function, as a checklist to prompt analysts to be more creative in regulatory design and evaluation. Precisely because conceptual CBA is not an entrenched and exclusive piece of any one agency’s historical lore, evaluating regulatory proposals within a CBA framework can open up new channels of thought and nudge regulators beyond a baseless enthusiasm for tried but perhaps less helpful models of regulation. Conceptual CBA involves a common language and mode of thought that could facilitate interagency dialogue by floating above any one statutory mandate or set of agency-specific regulatory goals. Such dialogue can improve thinking about CBA-related problems (for example, how to phase in or randomize regulation so as to generate useful information while meeting legitimate expectations about equal treatment under the law). 450 Thinking through conceptual CBA for a rule can lead to novel insights about how the rule is (or is not) similar to rules issued by other agencies, or how it might generate unintended consequences.

Fourth and most broadly, and with the greatest potential value, conceptual CBA/FR can facilitate improvements in quantified CBA/FR. Quantified CBA/FR, after all, would be highly valuable if it could generate precise and reliable estimates of the social costs and benefits of a regulatory change. Anything that promotes the long-term research agenda needed for reliable, precise quantitative CBA/FR has high potential value. To pursue that agenda, it would be useful for financial agencies to frame the questions that they face in evaluating regulations in terms of conceptual CBA, so as to stimulate and guide research. Research in economics, sociology, psychology, and other relevant fields proceeds along paths that are not random, but shaped by incentives, social cues, and psychological rewards. If agencies ask pointed research questions in their rulemaking proposals, they will encourage private researchers to answer those questions. Private actors with an interest in the answers may fund such research; tenure can be granted in part on the ground that an academic has answered a socially valuable question; and grant proposals are more likely to be funded if they relate to research topics that have direct potential value to regulatory agencies.

For conceptual CBA to be useful in this way, however, careful attention must be paid to institutional details, where the devil always lurks. Conceptual CBA/FR will not be useful in stimulating thought or guiding research if it consists of a simple, abstract list of the benefits and costs of a category of regulations. For example, it is correct in most instances for the SEC to include in the category of qualitative benefits “investor protection” and “investor confidence,” but it would be useless to leave things at that. How, precisely, does a rule improve confidence—through which channels? How does improved confidence constitute a social benefit—how does it affect the cost of capital? Nor will conceptual CBA/FR be useful if it consists of lengthy and opaque boilerplate circumlocutions designed to deflect or confuse judicial review rather than actually communicate to researchers or those who fund, evaluate, or publicize research.

A review of CBA conducted by the financial regulatory agencies demonstrates that fleshing out the benefits of financial regulation is a largely incomplete conceptual task, one that I hope the case studies in Part III will help advance. Similarly, indirect or systemic costs of regulation remain undeveloped. CBA/FR proponents have a strong point when they mock past CBA/FR efforts as exercises in “paperclip counting.” 451 Those who are unhappy with the financial agencies are striving to promote quantified CBA through law in part because they rightly worry that regulatory practices that focus only on easily quantified subsets of costs in isolation will achieve little good.

The question, then, is how to encourage financial regulators to engage in meaningful, detailed conceptual CBA for its own sake—which should enhance public understanding and may also assist regulators themselves—but also because more and better conceptual CBA should stimulate research on quantitative CBA by making more apparent the key quantities to be estimated, and so by stimulating academics to think harder about research designs that would permit that quantification. How can lawmakers or law affirmatively encourage the use of conceptual CBA to stimulate thought and innovation? While a detailed set of proposals is beyond the scope of this Article, 452 suffice it to say here that the challenge is primarily managerial, not methodological, a challenge not susceptible to simple legal commands or conventional judicial review. The challenge is not going to be met by specifying in meta-regulations methods to be used to conduct CBA/FR, but by using law and the lawmaking process to encourage expert agencies to better manage their resources and rulemaking processes in the short run—with the long-run goal of facilitating reliable, precise, quantified CBA/FR.

This Article has attempted to fill a significant gap in writing about CBA. It has shown how CBA/FR analysis would be conducted if—as advocated by some members of Congress, the D.C. Circuit, and legal academia—the law extended the current requirements that executive agencies engage in CBA to financial agencies, and required those agencies to produce as part of their rulemaking quantified CBA that could be subject to review under the requirements of the agencies’ authorizing statutes and the APA. Detailed case studies of six rules reveal that precise, reliable, quantified CBA remains unfeasible. Quantified CBA of such rules can be no more than “guesstimated,” and is not a true alternative to expert judgment—it is simply judgment in (numerical) disguise. As a result, for the near future, at least, judicial review of quantified CBA of financial regulation is not likely to generate benefits that exceed its costs. Until CBA/FR passes CBA’s own test, no new legal mandates should be adopted to require such review and more serious attention should be given to how to improve the capacities of the agencies to improve the reliability and precision of CBA in practice.

Volume 133’s Emerging Scholar of the Year: Robyn Powell

Announcing the eighth annual student essay competition, announcing the ylj academic summer grants program, responses to this article, cost-benefit analysis of financial regulations: a response to criticisms, financial regulation and cost-benefit analysis, economists in the room at the sec.

Throughout, I use the awkward acronym “CBA/FR” to flag that the analysis focuses on CBA of financial regulation, and that my conclusions may but do not necessarily carry over to CBA in other regulatory domains Part IV.A, infra , discusses potential differences between financial and other regulation.

Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub L. No. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010) [hereinafter Dodd-Frank Act]. A trade group recently sued to enjoin the most prominent rule under the Dodd-Frank Act, the Volcker Rule, in part on grounds that the agencies ignored economic effects of one small part of the rule on small banks. Matthew Goldstein & Peter Eavis , Banks’ Suit Tests Limits of Resisting Volcker Rule , N.Y. Times: DealBook (Dec. 24, 2013, 8:13 PM), http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2013/12/24/banks-suit-tests-limits-of-resisting-volcker-rule [http://perma.cc/Y78M-CKY7]. For the plaintiff’s motion for an emergency stay in the case, see Emergency Motion of Petitioners for Stay of Agency Action Pending Review, Am. Bankers Ass’n v. Fed. Reserve, No. 13-1310 (D.C. Cir. Dec. 24, 2013). On the current state of the law of CBA/FR, see infra Part II.A; for a discussion of the Volcker Rule and the trade group’s lawsuit, see infra Part III.D.

See Regulatory Tracker , Davis Polk & Wardwell LLP , http://www davispolk.com/dodd-frank/regulatory-tracker [http://perma.cc/G7PQ-5LHZ] .

See, eg. , Comm. on Capital Mkts . Regulation , A Balanced Approach to Cost-Benefit Analysis Reform 3, 9 (2013) [hereinafter CCMR Report ] (citing the Dodd-Frank Act as the reason for Congress to pass a law requiring CBA by independent agencies and noting that “the SEC and the CFTC still often fall short of conducting meaningful cost-benefit analysis of new regulations”); see also Hester Peirce, Economic Analysis by Federal Financial Regulators , 9 J.L. Econ. & Pol’y 569 (2013).

See, for example, the Independent Agency Regulatory Analysis Act of 2013, S 1173, 113th Cong., described infra Part II. For other bills, see infra note 144 .

CCMR Report, supra note 4, at 4 (using legislative history to argue that the National Securities Markets Improvement Act of 1996, Pub L. No. 104-290, 110 Stat. 3416 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 15 U.S.C.) requires the SEC to conduct CBA based on the statutory requirement that the SEC consider “efficiency” as one of a number of factors in rulemaking); Paul Rose & Christopher Walker , Ctr. for Capital Mkts . Competitiveness, The Importance of Cost-Benefit Analysis in Financial Regulation 24-33 (2013) [hereinafter CCMC Report ]. Critics also point to an efflorescence of decisions by the D.C. Circuit striking down SEC regulations as “arbitrary and capricious” under the Administrative Procedure Act (APA), 5 U.S.C. §§ 500-596 (1946), because of the agency’s failure to “consider” certain costs as part of its “efficiency” analysis; these cases are discussed in Part II below. Critics also note that the Commodity Exchange Act, Pub. L. No. 74-675, 49 Stat. 1491 (1936) (codified as amended at 7 U.S.C. §§ 1-27f) requires the CFTC to “consider the costs and benefits” of its regulatory actions. Id. § 19(a)(1). The Consumer Financial Protection Bureau is required to consider the “potential benefits and costs” as part of its rulemaking authority. Dodd-Frank Act § 1022.

Bus Roundtable v. SEC, 647 F.3d 1144 (D.C. Cir. 2011). I discuss this case in more detail in Part II below. See infra notes 114 - 125 and accompanying text. The decision was written by Judge Douglas Ginsburg, joined by Chief Judge David Sentelle and Judge Janice Brown, each appointed by a Republican President. Commentators have extensively criticized this decision, see infra note 114 , but it remains a binding precedent. For completeness, I note that the U.S. Chamber of Commerce, a party to the case, paid two professors who wrote a report defending the decision. See CCMC Report , supra note 6, at ii (discussing “financial and administrative support” for the report).

Nat’l Ass’n of Mfrs v. SEC, 956 F. Supp. 2d. 43 (D.D.C. 2013), aff’d in part , 748 F.3d 18 (D.C. Cir. 2014). The trial court decision was by Judge Robert L. Wilkins, who was subsequently nominated to the D.C. Circuit by President Obama, only to have his nomination filibustered by Senate Republicans. Todd Ruger , Senate Blocks Robert Wilkins’ Nomination to D.C. Circuit , Legal Times: BLT (Nov. 18, 2013, 6:44 PM), http://legaltimes.typepad.com/blt/2013/11/senate-blocks-robert-wilkins-nomination-to-dc-circuit.html [http://perma.cc/75P8-PYM6]. This occurrence helped prompt the Senate to abolish filibusters of lower court appointments. Jeremy W. Peters, In Landmark Vote, Senate Limits Use of the Filibuster , N.Y. Times , Nov. 21, 2013, http://www.nytimes.com/2013/11/22/us/politics/reid-sets-in-motion-steps-to-limit-use-of-filibuster.html [http://perma.cc/68ME-L8VL]. Judge Wilkins was confirmed to the D.C. Circuit under the Senate’s new rules. Pete Kasperowicz , Senate Confirms Third Judicial Nominee , The Hill (Jan. 13, 2014, 6:22 PM), http://thehill.com/blogs/floor-action/votes/195305-senate-confirms-wilkins-to-dc-court [http://perma.cc/6GA5-84ZW]. Earlier, a panel of the D.C. Circuit upheld a decision of the Office of Thrift Supervision against a CBA-based challenge, Stilwell v. Office of Thrift Supervision, 569 F.3d 514 (2009), and another Obama-appointed judge upheld a decision of the CFTC against a CBA-based challenge in 2012, despite the CFTC’s not having quantified the benefits or certain costs of the rule, Inv. Co. Inst. v. Commodity Futures Trading Comm., 891 F. Supp. 2d 162 (2012).

For a different but consistent critique of judicial review of agency decisions under conditions of uncertainty, see Adrian Vermeule , Rationally Arbitrary Decisions (in Administrative Law) (Harvard Law Sch, Working Paper No. 13-24, 2013), http://ssrn.com/abstract=2239155 [http://perma.cc/5AY8-WN7L] (arguing that courts should defer to agencies when agencies must act under conditions of uncertainty, even when the action is arbitrary).

In a related paper, I make further recommendations on how law and legal institutions can promote good CBA/FR as policy analysis, without risking the negative consequences of judicially enforced quantification See John C. Coates IV, Towards Better Cost-Benefit Analysis: An Essay on Regulatory Management , 78 Law & Contemp. Probs. ( forthcoming 2015), http://ssrn.com/abstract=2471682 [http://perma.cc/W5KF-44KT].

For overviews outside the financial regulatory context, see Matthew D Adler & Eric Posner, New Foundations of Cost-Benefit Analysis (2006); Cass R. Sunstein , The Cost-Benefit State: The Future Of Regulatory Protection (2002) [hereinafter Sunstein , The Cost-Benefit State] ; and Cass R. Sunstein , Risk and Reason (2003).

Supporters and critics of CBA alike tend to elide distinctions between different meanings of “cost-benefit analysis” Supporters—who, ironically, often defend CBA as promoting transparency—elide these distinctions to make CBA look appealing to the broadest possible audience, including skeptics and optimists about quantification, advocates of regulation and deregulation, regulators and the regulated, and intended regulatory beneficiaries and taxpayers. Critics of CBA elide the distinctions because they see efforts to promote CBA as policy as a step on a slippery slope to CBA law. Of late, others have taken a more nuanced position, supporting CBA/FR as policy without supporting CBA/FR law. See, e.g. , Bruce Kraus & Connor Raso , Rational Boundaries for SEC Cost-Benefit Analysis , 30 Yale J. on Reg. 289 (2013).

Lawyers negotiating contracts know the difference, too For example, they do not view a clause requiring a party to act reasonably or the like as innocuous: it is a “get” by the counterparty and a “give” by the party subject to the requirement.

Part IV, infra , develops this point in further detail

See Edward Sherwin, The Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Lessons from the SEC’s Stalled Mutual Fund Reform Effort , 12 Stan J.L. Bus. & Fin. 1, 47 (2006) (arguing that “[ t]he SEC’s failure to express the costs and benefits of its proposed rulemakings in numerical terms represents a significant shortcoming in its analysis”); see also U.S. Gov’t Accountability Office, Dodd-Frank Act Regulations: Implementation Could Benefit from Additional Analyses and Coordination 17-18 (Nov. 2011) (“Without monetized or quantified benefits and costs, or an understanding of the reasons they cannot be monetized or quantified, it is difficult for businesses and consumers to determine if the most cost-beneficial regulatory alternative was selected . . . .”).

For a discussion of these Executive Orders, see infra text accompanying note 79

Robert W Hahn et al., Assessing Regulatory Impact Analyses: The Failure of Agencies To Comply with Executive Order 12,866 , 23 Harv . J.L. & Pub. Pol’y 859, 861, 864 n.22 (1999-2000) (citing Exec. Order No. 12,866 § 6(a)(3)(C)(ii), 3 C.F.R. § 638, 645 (1993)). The authors acknowledge that the agencies were required to quantify costs and benefits only to “the extent feasible,” id. at 864 (citing Exec. Order No. 12,866, 3 C.F.R. § 645), and that “[ i ]t is arguably not always possible or desirable to monetize all benefits and costs,” id. at 864 n.18 (citing Exec. Order No. 12,866, 3 C.F.R. § 638-39; Office of Mgmt. & Budget, Economic Analysis of Federal Regulations Under Executive Order 12,866 (Jan. 11, 1996)). More recently, supporters of proposed legislative CBA mandates, including former commissioners of some of the independent agencies, have argued in favor of the bill on the ground that “not one of the 21 major rules issued by independent agencies in 2012 was based on a complete, quantified ” CBA. Letter from Nancy Nord et al. to Thomas R. Carper, Chair of the Senate Homeland Sec. and Gov’t Affairs Comm., and Thomas A. Coburn, Ranking Member of the Senate Homeland Sec. and Gov’t Affairs Comm. 2 (June 18, 2013) (emphasis added), http://www.portman.senate.gov/public/index.cfm/files/ serve ?File _id=8eb0dbd9-5631-4878-bfb2-e040407cf0ba [http://perma.cc/BB9B-HER8].

412 F3d 133, 144 (D.C. Cir. 2005).

Robert W Hahn, The Economic Analysis of Regulation: A Response to the Critics , 71 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1021, 1049-50 (2004) (rebutting critiques of CBA by noting that it “does not require that costs and benefits be expressed in the same units or that agencies monetize benefits that may not be quantifiable” and arguing that CBA should “be careful to reflect those uncertainties and account for qualitative factors”); Cass R. Sunstein , Nonquantifiable (May 1, 2013) (unpublished manuscript), http://ssrn.com/abstract=2259279 [http://perma.cc/H6N8-KZTT].

Office of Management and Budget guidelines are not entirely consistent on whether CBA entails quantification On the one hand, they emphasize that CBA should contain, in addition to quantification, the specification of baselines, alternatives, and a qualitative description of how a rule will produce benefits and what side effects it may have, Circular A-4: Regulatory Analysis , Off. Mgmt. & Budget 2 (2003) [hereinafter OMB Guidance ], http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/assets/regulatory_matters_pdf/a-4.pdf [http://perma.cc/TZ3F-S8UU], and they explicitly provide that where full monetization of all costs and benefits is not feasible, agencies should relate what can be quantified to what cannot be, so as to specify how large unquantified benefits could be or how small unquantified costs could be before a rule would “yield zero net benefits,” id. On the other hand, the guidelines contain statements suggesting that CBA entails full quantification; for example, the guidelines state that “[a] distinctive feature of [CBA] is that both benefits and costs are expressed in monetary units, which allows you to evaluate different regulatory options with a variety of attributes using a common measure.” Id. at 6.

Letter from Nancy Nord et al to Thomas R. Carper and Thomas A. Coburn , supra note 17 .

Kenneth J Arrow et al., Is There a Role for Benefit-Cost Analysis in Environmental, Health, and Safety Regulation ? , 272 Science 221, 222 (1996). Neither Arrow et al. nor Hahn et al., supra note 17 , provide evidence or cite to research supporting their views that quantification “should be possible” in “most” instances as applied to executive agencies. Sunstein likewise asserts without evidence that quantification will be impossible only in “rare” instances: “In the most extreme (and admittedly rare) cases, agencies may be operating under circumstances of ignorance , in which they cannot specify either outcomes or probabilities.” Sunstein , supra note 19, at 7.

For discussions, see, for example, Frank Ackerman & Lisa Heinzerling , Priceless: On Knowing The Price of Everything and the Value of Nothing (2004); David S Brookshire et al., Valuing Public Goods: A Comparison of Survey and Hedonic Approaches , 72 Am. Econ. Rev . 165 (1982) ; David S. Bullock & Nicholas Minot, On Measuring the Value of a Nonmarket Good Using Market Data , 88 Am. J. Agric. Econ. 961 (2006); and Karl- Göran Mäler , A Method of Estimating Social Benefits from Pollution Control , 73 Swedish J. Econ . 121 (1971).

See infra Part III for further discussion of the relevant non-market goods affected by financial regulation

Consultative Document: Assessment Methodologies for Identifying Non-Bank Non-Insurer Global Systemically Important Financial Institutions , Fin Stability Bd. & Int’l Org. Sec. Comm’ns 3 (Jan. 8, 2014), http://www.financialstabilityboard.org/publications/r_140108.pdf [http://perma.cc/LS8E-TAHJ] (identifying three transmission mechanisms for systemic risk: (1) direct exposure to failed institutions; (2) forced asset liquidations by failed institutions that disrupt trading or funding in key markets; and (3) disruption of a critical service or function without substitutes); see also Stephen L. Schwarcz , Systemic Risk , 97 Geo. L.J. 193 (2008) (identifying relationships between markets and institutions and noting how risk can spread through interconnected financial systems).

OMB Guidance, supra note 20, at 2

5 US.C. § 706(2)(A) (2012).

Eg. , OMB Guidance, supra note 20.

Eg. , Eric Posner & E. Glen Weyl , Benefit-Cost Analysis for Financial Regulation , 103 Am . Econ. Rev.: Papers & Proc. 393, 397 (2013) (arguing that CBA “should be applied to the introduction of new [derivatives] products into markets by private participants”). This approach is close to the one currently used in regulation of mutual funds in both the United States and the European Union, which generally forbid innovation in the design of collective investments without prior regulatory approval; as a result, proponents are generally required to demonstrate that the benefits of the design will outweigh its risks to investors. See John C. Coates IV, Reforming the Taxation and Regulation of Mutual Funds: A Comparative Legal and Economic Analysis , 1 J. Legal Analysis 591 (2009).

5 US.C. § 553 (2012).

See, eg. , Matthew D. Adler & Eric A. Posner, Introduction, Cost -Benefit Analysis: Legal, Economic, and Philosophical Perspectives , 29 J. Legal Stud. 837, 841 (2000) (“Much has been written about whether the cost-benefit analysis executive orders have actually influenced the behavior of agencies. Knowledgeable scholars in this area seem to doubt that the executive orders have had much influence.”).

No published study examines empirically whether CBA produces benefits that outweigh its costs—whether CBA in practice passes its own test Closest are studies assessing whether ex ante quantitative CBA by executive agencies produced CBA that was consistent with retrospective estimates. E.g ., Robert W. Hahn et al., Do Federal Regulations Reduce Mortality ? 19 (2000) (finding that nine of twenty-four rules passed a cost-benefit test); Winston Harrington et al., On the Accuracy of Regulatory Cost Estimates , 19 J. Pol’y Analysis & Mgmt . 297, 314 (2000) (finding that for fourteen of twenty-eight Occupational Safety and Health Administration or EPA rules, total costs were overestimated, while for only three were they underestimated, and overestimates were often due to difficulties in determining the baseline and incomplete compliance). These studies do not provide reliable evidence about whether CBA would pass its own test, because they do not model the counterfactual of interest: how does regulation under CBA compare to regulation without it? For that analysis, one would need to match rules subject to CBA with those not subject to CBA, and study which did better at achieving net benefits. One method may be to exploit the fact that “economically significant rules” (ESRs) are subject to more stringent CBA under OMB Guidance, supra note 20, than other rules, so one could compare outcomes for rules just above and below the ESR threshold. Any objection that this question is simply too hard to study should lead to a similar conclusion as the one reached by this Article—in other words, that CBA/FR itself is unreliable.

Eg ., Matthew D. Adler & Eric A. Posner, Rethinking Cost-Benefit Analysis , 109 Yale L.J. 165, 239 (1999) (tentatively recommending CBA over “ unidimensional ” or “ nonaggregative ” decision procedure alternatives).

Eg. , Cass R. Sunstein , The Arithmetic of Arsenic , 90 Geo. L.J . 2255, 2289-90 (2002) (defending CBA on the ground that, although the bottom-line quantification of the arsenic rule was so uncertain that no conclusion could be reached from it, it was successful because it allowed the government to be “transparent” about why the rule’s net benefits were uncertain). Transparency is often presented as an obviously good thing. Id .; Adler & Posner, supra note 35, at 239 (asserting the “inherent transparency of CBA itself” and noting that oversight bodies such as OMB can prevent agencies from misusing CBA or applying it in a way that decreases transparency). But see Troy A. Paredes , Blinded by the Light: Information Overload and Its Consequences for Securities Regulation , 81 Wash. U. L.Q. 417, 444-45 (2003) (arguing that information overload can lead to disclosures that are not meaningful or effective).

Eg ., Cass R. Sunstein , Cost-Benefit Default Principles , 99 Mich. L. Rev. 1651, 1662, 1709 (2001) (stating that “ the case for cost-benefit analysis is strengthened by the fact that interest groups are often able to use . . . cognitive problems strategically, thus fending off regulation that is desirable or pressing for regulation when the argument on its behalf is fragile ”; and noting the risk that, if permitted to adopt rules that do not pass a CBA test, agencies “ will conceal an effort to placate powerful private groups not having a strong claim to governmental assistance ”) ; W. Kip Viscusi , Risk Equity , 29 J. Legal Stud. 843 (2000) (agencies sometimes adopt rules that benefit private interests) .

Adler & Posner, supra note 35, at 245 (“CBA is a useful decision procedure and it should be routinely used by agencies CBA is superior to rival method[s] . . . [and] allows agencies to take into account all relevant influences on overall well-being . . . and . . . to weigh the advantages and disadvantages in a clear and systematic way . . . . ”).

Compare Sunstein , supra note 37, at 1662 (arguing that unless people “are asked to seek a full accounting, they are likely to focus on small parts of problems” and explaining that CBA “is a way of producing [a] full accounting” and is a “natural corrective” for “systematic errors” and “misperceptions of facts” caused by the use of “rules of thumbs, or heuristics”), with Richard A Posner, Cost-Benefit Analysis: Definition, Justification, and Comment on Conference Papers , 29 J. Legal Stud. 1153, 1161-62 (2000) (critiquing the justification of CBA as a corrective for cognitive biases), and Joshua D. Wright & Douglas H. Ginsburg, Behavioral Law and Economics: Its Origins, Fatal Flaws, and Implications for Liberty , 106 Nw. U. L. Rev. 1033 (2012) (critiquing Sunstein’s research and attempts to account for cognitive biases in policymaking).

Despite being generally in favor of CBA, Adler and Posner acknowledge this point, but they do not develop it as a theoretical reason to resist legalizing CBA Adler & Posner, supra note 35, at 172 (“Agencies sometimes appear to use CBA to rationalize decisions made on other grounds.”).

Paredes , supra note 36, at 420 (“[ T]he specter of information overload casts doubt on the long-held belief and policy choice that more disclosure is better than less”). Paredes was a Republican Commissioner of the SEC until 2013, and as Commissioner, Paredes was a strong proponent of CBA. See Troy A. Paredes , Remarks at AICPA Council Spring Meeting (May 17, 2012), http://www.sec.gov/News/Speech/Detail/Speech/1365171490500# .VEMV6ecdVEA [ http://perma.cc/4JMC-JLK9] (“[The SEC] must engage in rigorous [CBA] when fashioning . . . securities law . . . . I have expressed these views several times before in advocating for rigorous [CBA] at the SEC.”); see also Alex Edmans et al., The Real Costs of Disclosure 2 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 19420, 2013) (arguing that “even if the actual act of disclosure is costless, high-disclosure policy can still be costly due to differential verifiability of some kinds of information”).

Duncan Kennedy, Cost-Benefit Analysis of Entitlement Problems: A Critique , 33 Stan L. Rev. 387, 443 (1981) (“[CBA] is arbitrary. It provides yet another medium for the introduction of political preferences through what seem merely necessary ‘practical’ assumptions of any analysis. . . . The focus on particular problems legitimates arbitrary assumptions and masks their political content.”) ; Amy Sinden , Cass Sunstein’s Cost-Benefit Lite: Economics for Liberals , 29 Colum. J. Envtl . L. 191, 194 (2011) (book review) (“The danger of CBA . . . lies in its false promise of determinacy, its pretense of objectivity and scientific accuracy. . . . [ T]his false promise . . . renders CBA . . . vulnerable to manipulation and . . . destructive to democratic decision-making, as . . . Sunstein’s analysis of the arsenic CBA amply demonstrates.”).

Eg. , Adler & Posner, supra note 35, at 169 & n.5 (citing Ajit K. Dasgupta & D.W. Pearce, Cost-Benefit Analysis: Theory and Practice 12-13 (1972)).

Flood Control Act of 1936, 33 US.C. § 701a (2012); see also Sherwin, supra note 15, at 6 (citing James T. Campen , Benefit, Cost, and Beyond: The Political Economy of Benefit-Cost Analysis 16 (1986)). Sherwin correctly notes but does not discuss an earlier statute, the River and Harbor Act of 1902, ch. 1079, § 3, 32 Stat. 331, 372. That statute directed the organization and authorized the funding of a board of engineers reporting to the Chief of Engineers of the United States Army. The board was directed “so far as in the opinion of the Chief of Engineers may be necessary” to review reports for proposed river and harbor improvements and submit recommendations and “have in view the amount and character of commerce existing or reasonably prospective which will be benefited by the improvement, and the relation of the ultimate cost of such work . . . to the public commercial interests involved, and the public necessity for the work.” 33 U.S.C. § 541 (2012). The board was instructed to do the same for past projects upon request by relevant congressional committees. Id.

Theodore M Porter, Trust in Numbers: The Pursuit of Objectivity in Science and Public Life 148-90 (1995).

Adler & Posner, supra note 35, at 194 (noting “an argument [they] believe has currency among economists although it is rarely defended in print . . is that CBA is desirable because there are no superior alternatives that provide determinate, or relatively determinate, prescriptions”).

Isaac Alfon & Peter Andrews, Cost-Benefit Analysis in Financial Regulation: How To Do It and How It Adds Value , Fin Services Authority, Sept. 1999, at 11 http://spi-romania.eu/admin/filemanager/files/bulgaria/0.4.fsa__cba_in_financial_regulation.pdf [http://perma.cc/XY93-BFA3].

Sinden , supra note 42, at 226-27

See Risk Versus Risk: Tradeoffs in Protecting Health and the Environment (John D Graham & Jonathan Baert Weiner eds ., 1995).

Henry M Levin, Cost-Effectiveness: A Primer 17-18 (1983).

An example is the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956, which bans banks from being owned by or affiliating with companies engaged in non-financial activities Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 § 4, 12 U.S.C. § 1843 (2010). The Federal Reserve Board and other banking agency regulations interpreting this statute do not engage in CBA when they evaluate whether an activity is prohibited by the statute.

Despite the repeal in the Gramm-Leach- Blilely Act, Pub L. No. 106-102, 113 Stat. 1338 (1999) (codified in scattered sections of 12 U.S.C.), of the Glass- Steagall Act of 1933, 48 Stat. 162, banks and companies that control banks are still banned from most non-financial activities and investments under the Bank Holding Company Act of 1956. The Volcker Rule is similar, as discussed infra Part III.D, in that it bans banks from specified activities.

OMB Guidance, supra 7note 71erm ing the ban and has signaled a desire to address the issue in the coming legisrting oil produced domestically.siona note 20 (suggesting the use of “judgment” or “professional judgment” fourteen times, including the use of formal Delphi methods for eliciting expert seat-of-the-pants estimates). On Delphi methods, see M. Granger Morgan & Max Henrion , Uncertainty: A Guide to Dealing with Uncertainty in Quantitative Risk and Policy Analysis 164-68 (1990). For a trenchant attack on CBA generally, arguing in favor of the use of “intelligent deliberation” as the alternative, see Henry S. Richardson, The Stupidity of the Cost-Benefit Standard , 29 J. Legal Stud. 971 (2000).

The expertise of the financial agencies includes vastly more firepower than is available to OIRA, which has a total staff of roughly fifty Office of Information and Regulatory Affairs (OIRA) Q & A’s , Off. Mgmt. & Budget (Nov. 2009), http://www.whitehouse.gov/omb/oira_qsandas [http://perma.cc/AA96-TFKU]. The Federal Reserve Board alone has 220 Ph.D. economists on staff. See Ryan Grim, Priceless: How the Federal Reserve Bought the Economics Profession , Huffington Post, Oct. 23, 2009, http://www.huffingtonpost.com /2009/09/07/priceless-how-the-federal_n_278805.html [http://perma.cc/M9AN-FZRL]. The SEC has more than fifty economists. See Economists , Sec. & Exch. Commission (Oct. 7, 2014), http://www.sec.gov/divisions/riskfin/economistbios.shtml [http://perma.cc/NT98-GHUU]. For a discussion of the careers of SEC Commissioners and staff, see John C. Coates IV, Private vs. Political Choice of Securities Regulation: A Political Cost/Benefit Analysis , 41 Va. J. Int’l L . 531 (2001).

Eg. , Cybersecurity Roundtable , Sec. & Exch. Comm’n (May 14, 2014), http://www.sec.gov/spotlight/cybersecurity-roundtable.shtml [ http://perma.cc/5XKY-R6KJ ] (example of consultation by SEC with experts); Office of Econ. Analysis, Economic Analysis of the Short Sale Price Restrictions Under the Regulation SHO Pilot , Sec. & Exchange Commission (Feb. 6, 2007), http://www.sec.gov/news/studies/2007/regshopilot020607.pdf [http://perma.cc/23G6-S9YC] (example of regulatory experiment); Office of Econ. Analysis, Study of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 Section 404 Internal Control over Financial Reporting Requirements , Sec. & Exchange Commission (2009) [ hereinafter Office of Econ. Analysis, Study of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act ] , http://www.sec.gov/news/studies/2009/sox-404_study.pdf [ http://perma.cc/5DBB-H45S ] (example of study including survey data).

See Final Report of the National Commission on the Causes of the Financial and Economic Crisis in the United States , Fin Crisis Inquiry Commission 27-82 (Jan. 2011), http://www.gpo.gov/fdsys/pkg/GPO-FCIC/pdf/GPO-FCIC.pdf [http://perma.cc/43W2-7WAU].

See Philip E Tetlock , Expert Political Judgment: How Good Is It? How Can We Know? (2005) ( noting that expert political opinion is often wrong); Tom Stark, Fed. Reserve Bank of Phila ., Realistic Evaluation of Real-Time Forecasts in the Survey of Professional Forecasters 2 (May 28, 2010) (unpublished paper), http://www.phil.frb.org/research-and-data/publications/research-rap/2010/realistic-evaluation-of-real-time-forecasts.pdf [http://perma.cc/W4GG-J84W] (concluding that expert economic forecasts beat “no change” forecasts and simple direct and indirect autoregression models, but performance of forecasts fell sharply for predictions more than three months in the future) .

See infra note 73

More specifically, the Rule calls for the Fed to set the federal funds rate (traditionally its principal instrument for setting monetary policy) at one plus 15 times the inflation rate plus 0.5 times the “output gap,” defined as the percentage deviation of actual GDP from “potential” GDP. See John B. Taylor, Discretion Versus Policy Rules in Practice , 39 Carnegie-Rochester Conf. Series on Pub. Pol’y 195, 202 (1993). “Potential” GDP is an estimate of “the trend growth in the productive capacity of the economy . . . an estimate of the level of GDP attainable when the economy is operating at a high rate of resource use . . . [that is, an estimate of] maximum sustainable output—the level of real GDP in a given year that is consistent with a stable rate of inflation.” CBO’s Method for Estimating Potential Output: An Update , Cong. Budget Off. 1 (Aug. 2001), http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/30xx/doc3020/potentialoutput.pdf [http://perma.cc/L68J-SMQV]. Although models of potential GDP vary, the CBO publishes estimates that are widely used, based on the “Solow growth model,” a simple projection of GDP based on two supply-side factors: “labor input (hours worked) and accumulation of physical capital (additions to the nation’s stock of plant and equipment).” Id. at 3.

See Taylor, supra note 66 , at 207-08 For prior theoretical work, see Finn E. Kydland & Edward C. Prescott, Rules Rather than Discretion: The Inconsistency of Optimal Plans , 85 J. Pol. Econ . 473 (1977).

In fact, Taylor has argued that the Federal Reserve has repeatedly deviated from his rule John B. Taylor, Getting Back on Track: Macroeconomic Policy Lessons from the Financial Crisis , 92 Fed. Res. Bank of St. Louis Rev . 165-76 (May/June 2010) [hereinafter Taylor, Getting Back on Track ]; John B. Taylor, A Historical Analysis of Monetary Policy Rules , in Monetary Policy Rules 319 (John B. Taylor ed., 1999) [hereinafter Taylor, A Historical Analysis ]. On the other hand, recently departed Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke, Federal Reserve Board members, and staff economists have argued the contrary—and, moreover, have claimed that Taylor’s 1993 formulation of his rule differs from his 1999 formulation. Ben Bernanke, Chairman, Fed. Reserve, Monetary Policy and the Housing Bubble, Speech at the Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association (Jan. 3, 2010), http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20100103a.htm [http://perma.cc/KT3L-6SVD]; Laurence Meyer, Dueling Taylor Rules , Macroeconomic Advisors: Monetary Pol ’ y Insights, Aug. 20, 2009; Glenn Rudebusch , The Fed’s Monetary Policy Response to the Current Crisis , 2009-17 Fed. Res. Bank of S.F. Econ. Letter (May 22, 2009).

Alex Nikolsko-Rzhevskyy & David H Papell , Taylor’s Rule Versus Taylor Rules 1 (Sept. 15, 2012) (unpublished paper), http://ssrn.com/abstract=1826363 [http://perma.cc/7U7U-Q552] (referring to the period under Greenspan from 1987 to 1992).

Compare Kydland & Prescott, supra note 67 , at 487 (advocating that Congress select a “simple and easily understood” monetary policy rule and have it take effect prospectively after a two-year delay—without explaining how such a law could be made binding on a future Congress), with Ricardo Reis, Central Bank Design , 27 J Econ. Persp . 17, 18 (2013) (stating that central banks’ objectives have usually been “vague”); id. at 19 (stating that “some discretion” may better allow a central bank to achieve even clearly stated objectives); id. at 25-26 (stating that central banks “always have some discretion”), and John B. Taylor, A Steadier Course for Monetary Policy , Testimony Before the Joint Economic Committee on “The Fed at 100: Can Monetary Policy Close the Growth Gap and Promote a Sound Dollar?” 3-4 (Apr. 18, 2013), http://www.stanford.edu/~johntayl/JEC%20Testimony%20-%20April%2018.pdf [http://perma.cc/8KB2-B5WA] (calling for a “return to a more rules-based policy” and a “gradual exit” from what he criticizes as unfortunate policy decisions, and not for a sudden or strict “rule” to set policy; declaring that, under his proposal, “while discretion would be constrained, it would not be eliminated”).

See infra notes 146-148 and accompanying text Even those who advocate greater Fed transparency—as reflected in the various bills known colloquially as “Audit the Fed” laws—would not subject the Fed’s monetary policy choices to either ex ante CBA requirements or ex post review by courts or another agency. See, e.g. , Federal Reserve Transparency Act of 2013, S. 209, 113th Cong. (2013) (proposing to repeal exemption from audit by the Comptroller General of the Federal Reserve, contained in 31 U.S.C. § 714, for various transactions, deliberations, and communications relating to, among other things, monetary policy).

Sewall Chan, From Tea Party Advocates, Anger at the Federal Reserve , NY. Times, Oct. 10, 2010, http://www.nytimes.com/2010/1 0/11/us/politics/11fed.html [http://perma.cc/74TA-GNYU] (describing Republican politicians’ criticisms of the Fed based on Fed policy decisions during the economic crisis).

On the overall goals pursued by the Fed, see What Is the Purpose of the Federal Reserve System ? , Board Governors Fed Res. Sys ., http://www.federalreserve.gov/faqs/about_12594.htm [http://perma.cc/TW9Z-ANYL] (outlining the Fed’s legal responsibilities and goals, including an effective payment system and a stable financial system). The Fed’s statutory mandate relating to monetary policy is narrower, consisting of seeking to maintain the “long run growth of the monetary and credit aggregates commensurate with the economy’s long run potential to increase production, so as to promote effectively the goals of maximum employment, stable prices, and moderate long-term interest rates.” 12 U.S.C. § 225a (2012). I am informed by close observers of Congress that the Office of Legislative Council—which provides confidential drafting advice to members of Congress and their staffs—routinely suggests exemptions for monetary policy from bills imposing procedural or other requirements on regulatory action, based on a strong norm of preserving the Fed’s independence in overseeing monetary policy.

See Roger E Backhouse, The Puzzle of Modern Economics: Science or Ideology? 117-37 (2010) (describing historical and ongoing debates within economics over whether and how to construct macroeconomic models, and detailing continuing disputes over the ability of such models to adequately forecast economic behavior).

The APA defines a “rule” as any “statement of general or particular applicability and future effect designed to implement, interpret, or prescribe law or policy” 5 U.S.C. § 551 (2012). If the pending bills did not exempt monetary policy, then any “statement” by the Federal Reserve Board meant to “implement . . . policy” would arguably require CBA/FR under the APA. Id.

OMB Guidance, supra note 20, at 2 (“You will find that you cannot conduct a good regulatory analysis according to a formula Conducting high-quality analysis requires competent professional judgment.”).

See Taylor, Getting Back on Track , supra note 70; Taylor, A Historical Analysis , supra note 70

Independent regulatory agencies are listed in the Paperwork Reduction Act of 1980 44 U.S.C. § 3502(5) (2012). Not all financial regulations are issued by independent agencies; the Department of Labor, which is an executive agency, promulgates regulations relevant to pension funds, for example, and is governed by the executive orders listed infra note 81.

Exec Order No. 12,291, 46 Fed. Reg. 13,193 (Feb. 17, 1981) (requiring, inter alia, CBA for new regulations), superseded by Exec. Order No. 12,866, 58 Fed. Reg. 51,735 (Sept. 30, 1993) (modestly amending prior CBA requirements, imposing heightened requirements for “significant regulatory action” and further requirements for actions likely to have an economic impact of $100 million per year (hereinafter, an “economically significant rulemaking”)), amended by Exec. Order No. 13,258, 67 Fed. Reg. 9385 (Feb. 26, 2002) (eliminating the role of the Vice President in the CBA process), supplemented by Exec. Order No. 13,563, 76 Fed. Reg. 3821 (Jan. 18, 2011). Under these orders, executive agencies are required to conduct quantified CBA to the extent feasible, to submit significant rules to OIRA in advance, to provide CBAs to OIRA, to wait until OIRA reviews the CBAs before publishing rules for public comment, and to publish CBAs with rules. Id. Independent agencies are required only to provide OMB with an annual agenda of significant regulatory actions for the upcoming year, including, “to the extent feasible and permitted by law,” a summary CBA. Id. Sherwin reports having reviewed these agendas for the SEC in the period leading up to 2006, and he found they did not generally include summary CBA. Sherwin, supra note 15, at 12. These executive orders were joined by the Unfunded Mandates Reform Act requirement that executive agencies, but not independent agencies, include written CBAs for each economically significant rulemaking. Unfunded Mandates Reform Act of 1995, Pub. L. No. 104-4, 109 Stat. 48 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 2 U.S.C.).

Eg. , Monetary Policy and the State of the Economy: Hearing Before the H. Comm. on Fin. Servs . , 113th Cong. 8 (2013) (statement of Federal Reserve Chairman Ben Bernanke that Federal Open Market Committee purchases of financial assets are conducted “within a [CBA] framework”); SEC Office of the Inspector Gen.,Compliance Handbook 38-39 (1999) (stating that SEC rule proposals should contain CBAs). This handbook reflected OMB’s best practices guidance issued in 1996, see Gov’t Accountability Office, GAO-12-151 Dodd-Frank Act Regulations: Implementation Could Benefit from Additional Analyses and Coordination n.14 (2011); see also Budget Hearing—Securities and Exchange Commission: Hearing Before the Fin. Servs . and Gen. Gov’t Subcomm . of the H. Comm. on Appropriations , 112th Cong. (2011) (statement of SEC Chairman Mary Schapiro), Federal News Service, Inc., transcript at 26-27; SEC Office of the Inspector General, Office of Audits, SEC OIG 499, Follow-Up Review of Cost-Benefit Analyses in Selected Dodd-Frank Rulemakings 6 (2012) (“SEC Chairman Arthur Levitt stated that there was an expectation that the SEC would perform cost-benefit analyses as part of the rulemaking process.”). See generally Barry D. Friedman, Regulation in the Reagan-Bush Era: The Eruption of Presidential Influence 78 (1995); Richard H. Pildes & Cass R. Sunstein , Reinventing the Regulatory State , 62 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1, 11-18 (1995); Peter L. Strauss, The Place of Agencies in Government: Separation of Powers & the Fourth Branch , 84 Colum. L. Rev. 573, 591-93 (1984).

Financial Services Act, 2012, amending inter alia sections 138I (Financial Conduct Authority) and 138J (Prudential Regulation Authority) of the Financial Services and Markets Act 2000 In striking contrast to the recent U.S. experience, the FSA and its successors’ rulemakings and CBA (while subject to judicial review) have not been subjected to numerous court decisions striking down rules for inadequate CBA. The only example of a court decision that even refers to CBA by the Financial Services Authority (FSA) is R (on the application of the British Bankers Association) v. FSA et al. , [2011] EWHC (Admin) 999 (Eng.), which rejected a challenge by a banking trade group to the handling of complaints about “Payment Protection Insurance” by the FSA and the Financial Ombudsman Service, which handles consumer financial complaints.

Pub L. No. 104-13, 109 Stat. 163 (1995) (codified at 44 U.S.C. §§ 3501-3520).

Pub L. No. 96-354, 94 Stat. 1164 (1980) (codified at 5 U.S.C. §§ 601-612). The RFA was one basis for the recent suit against the Volcker Rule by the American Bar Association. See infra note 341.

Technically, the reports are submitted to the head of the GAO, the Comptroller General Contract with America Advancement Act of 1996, Pub. L. No. 104-121, 110 Stat. 847 (1996) (codified as amended in 5 U.S.C. §§ 801 et seq.). This statute exempts monetary policy by the Federal Reserve Board and the Federal Open Market Committee. 5 U.S.C. § 807.

5 US.C. § 804. Under the statute, major rules do not go into effect for sixty days, and Congress has the power to veto “major rules” by joint resolution passed within that period, subject to presidential veto of the joint resolution. 5 U.S.C. §§ 801-802. Courts have interpreted this statute to preclude judicial review of agency compliance with the statute, including agency determinations of whether a rule is “major.” See, e.g. , Via Christi Reg’l Med. Ctr., Inc. v. Leavitt, 509 F.3d 1259, 1271 n.11 (10th Cir. 2007) (“The Congressional Review Act specifically precludes judicial review of an agency’s compliance with its terms.”); Operation of the Missouri River Sys. Litig ., 363 F. Supp. 2d 1145, 1173 (D. Minn. 2004) (agency’s determination under CRA that a rule is not a “major rule” is not subject to judicial review); see also Montanans for Multiple Use v. Barbouletos , 568 F.3d 225 (D.C. Cir. 2009); Tex. Sav . & Cmty . Bankers Ass’n v. Fed. Hous . Fin. Bd., 201 F.3d 551 (5th Cir. 2000).

Eg. , GAO-03-933R Report U nder 5 U.S.C. § 801(a)(2)(A) on a Major Rule , U.S. Gov’t Accountability O ff. (June 25, 2003), http://www.gao.gov/assets/90/83472.pdf [http://perma.cc/CEG8-WVRH] (reviewing the rule proposed by the SEC for the implementation of section 404 of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act, discussed more infra Part III.A); GAO-14-147R, Report U nder 5 U.S.C. § 801(a)(2)(A) on a Major Rule , U.S. Gov’t Accountability Off. (Oct. 30, 2013) , http://www.gao.gov/assets/660/658810.pdf [http://perma.cc/VXV7-A35V] (reviewing the rule proposed by the Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC) and the Federal Reserve to implement Basel III, discussed more infra Part III.C); Off. Info. & Regulatory Affairs, 2012 Report to Congress on the Benefits and Costs of Federal Regulations and Unfunded Mandates on State, Local, and Tribal Entities , Off. Mgmt. Budget app. C , http:// http://www.whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/inforeg/2012_cb/2012_cost_benefit_report.pdf [http://perma.cc/2N6B-NKL7] (assessing CBA of “major rules” issued by independent agencies in the prior fiscal year).

Chamber of Commerce v SEC, 412 F.3d 133 (D.C. Cir. 2005).

412 F3d at 142 (citing 15 U.S.C. § 80a-2(c) (2012)).

National Securities Markets Improvement Act, Pub L. No. 104-290, § 106, 110 Stat. 3416, 3425 (1996) (codified at 15 U.S.C. § 80a-2). Identical requirements were added to the other federal securities laws. Id.

412 F3d at 144.

Id at 144. The third failing did not raise CBA issues, and arose under the APA directly: the SEC had not formally considered a disclosure alternative to its proposals, in which funds would prominently disclose whether they had independent chairs. Here, the court pointed to the fact that two dissenting Commissioners had suggested the alternative, along with a number of commentators, and that the SEC’s only stated reasons for not considering it were that it had no obligation to consider every alternative raised, that it did consider other alternatives, and that Congress in the ICA itself had not relied on disclosure to police conflicts of interest in funds. To this, the court noted, “[ T]hat the Congress required more than disclosure with respect to some matters governed by the ICA does not mean it deemed disclosure insufficient with respect to all such matters.” Id. at 144-46.

Id at 137 (citing Investment Company Governance, 69 Fed. Reg. 46,387 n.81) (stating that “[ w]e have no reliable basis for estimating those costs”).

Id at 144 (“The Commission did violate the APA by failing adequately to consider the costs mutual funds would incur in order to comply with the conditions.”); accord id. at 136.

The only precedent cited by the court in its critique of the SEC’s CBA was Public Citizen v Federal Motor Carrier Safety Administration , 374 F.3d 1209 (D.C. Cir. 2004). In that case, an executive (not independent) agency that was specifically required by statute to “consider the costs and benefits” of its regulation was held to have violated a distinct statutory requirement to “ deal[ ] with . . . fatigue-related issues pertaining to . . . vehicle safety,” which the court there interpreted as requiring the agency to collect and analyze data on the costs and benefits of a specific possible regulation. Id. at 1211-12 (citing 49 U.S.C. §§ 31502, 31506, 31136 (2012)); see also id. at 1221 (“This directive, in our view, required the agency, at a minimum, to collect and analyze data on the costs and benefits.”). No specific directive of that kind was at issue in Chamber of Commerce , only the open-ended directive for the SEC to consider the effects of its rules on “efficiency, competition, and capital formation.” 412 F.3d at 140 (citing 15 U.S.C. § 80a-2(c) (2012)).

See, eg. , Mas- Collel et al., supra note 32, at 127, 152-53 (discussing “efficiency” without reference to quantitative data).

See Bowman Transp, Inc. v. Ark.-Best Freight Sys ., Inc., 419 U.S. 281, 285-86 (1974). After Chamber of Commerce , the D.C. Circuit has held that courts should be “particularly deferential in matters implicating predictive judgments,” Rural Cellular Ass’n v. FCC, 588 F.3d 1095, 1105 (D.C. Cir. 2009), which led another panel of the D.C. Circuit to hold that the APA “imposes no general obligation on agencies to produce empirical evidence” when it is not in the agency’s record. Stilwell v. Office of Thrift Supervision, 569 F.3d 514, 519 (D.C. Cir. 2009).

Nat’l Wildlife Fed’n v EPA, 286 F.3d 554, 563 (D.C. Cir. 2002). This fact has led another panel of the D.C. Circuit, after Chamber of Commerce , to announce sweepingly that courts should “review . . . cost-benefit analysis deferentially.” Nat’l Ass’n of Home Builders v. EPA, 682 F.3d 1032, 1040 (D.C. Cir. 2012).

OMB Guidance, supra note 20 The OMB does not specify that an agency engaging in quantification “to the extent feasible” must quantify costs on a conditional basis.

647 F3d 1144 (D.C. Cir. 2011).

For the total number of major rules, see Office of Info & Regulatory Affairs, Office of Mgmt. & Budget, Exec. Office of the President, 2012 Report to Congress on the Benefits and Costs of Federal Regulations and Unfunded Mandates on State, Local, and Tribal Entities app. c (2012).

Goldstein v. SEC, 451 F.3d 873 (D.C. Cir. 2006).

Fin . Planning Ass’n v. SEC, 482 F.3d 481 (D.C. Cir. 2007).

PAZ Sec., Inc. v. SEC, 494 F.3d 1059 (D.C. Cir. 2007).

Am . Equity Inv. Life Ins. Co. v. SEC, 613 F.3d 166 (D.C. Cir. 2010).

Chamber of Commerce v SEC, 443 F.3d 890 (2006) (holding that the SEC’s re-proposal of the mutual fund governance rules violated the APA because the SEC relied on materials not in the public record and had not reopened the rule for public comment). Some commentators have suggested that the SEC’s rapid re-adoption of its rule with the cost estimates called for by the D.C. Circuit in Chamber of Commerce I shows that it was less than diligent in failing to provide the cost estimates in the first release. E.g. , CCMC Report , supra note 6, at 30; Sherwin, supra note 15, at 164. This criticism is unfair, because it fails to explain why the SEC should have understood that it had an obligation to provide that cost information in its first release; at the time of that release, neither the APA nor NSMIA nor court precedents would have made it apparent that the cost considerations—referred to by the Chamber of Commerce’s own report as “relatively minor,” CCMC Report, supra note 6, at 30—would be an independently important component of the SEC’s regulatory analysis, or were otherwise required to be set forth in the release. It is even more deceptive to imply that the SEC was able in its second release to do something it had said it could not do in its first release, as the CCMC report suggests, id. ( noting that “the court’s incredulity about the SEC’s position that the agency could not determine these costs proved true”), because the SEC’s position was not that it could not estimate conditional cost estimates, but only that these conditional cost estimates could not be translated into an actual aggregate compliance estimate—which it never provided, even in its second release.

Nat’l Ass’n of Mfrs v. SEC, 748 F.3d 359 (D.C. Cir. 2014).

Inv Co. Inst. v. CFTC, 891 F. Supp. 2d 162, 215 (D.D.C. 2012) (“While the CFTC did not calculate the costs of the Final Rule down to the dollar-and-cent, it reasonably considered the costs and benefits of the Final Rule, and decided that the benefits outweigh the costs.”).

Stilwell v Office of Thrift Supervision, 569 F.3d 514 (D.C. Cir. 2009).

See cases cited supra notes 103-112

956 F Supp. 2d 43, 53 (D.D.C. 2013) (“All of those cases involved rules or regulations that were proposed and adopted by the SEC of its own accord, with the Commission having independently perceived a problem within its purview and having exercised its own judgment to craft a rule or regulation aimed at that problem.”).

See Brandice Canes- Wrone , Bureaucratic Decisions and the Composition of the Lower Courts , 47 Am J. Pol. Sci. 205, 205 (2003) (using a dataset of Army Corps of Engineers decisions from 1988 to 1996 to conclude that “judicial ideology significantly affects bureaucratic decision making,” consistent with the idea that agencies may seek to shelter decisions from court review by obtaining Congressional mandates); Yehonatan Givati , Strategic Statutory Interpretation by Administrative Agencies , 12 Am. L. & Econ. Rev. 95 (2010) (finding that, in a theoretical model, stricter judicial review of agency action can result in “safer” statutory interpretations by the agency, due to the relative shift in utility of safe and aggressive interpretations); M. Elizabeth Magill, Agency Choice of Policymaking Form , 71 U. Chi. L. Rev. 1383, 1437-42 (2004) (noting that agencies can and do choose among rulemaking, enforcement, and informal guidance for various reasons and that judicial review is affected by and affects these choices); Matthew C. Stephenson, The Strategic Substitution Effect: Textual Plausibility, Procedural Formality, and Judicial Review of Agency Statutory Interpretations , 120 Harv . L. Rev . 528 (2006) (concluding that procedural formality substitutes for textual interpretation of statutes that authorize agency actions); Emerson H. Tiller, Controlling Policy by Controlling Process: Judicial Influence on Regulatory Decision Making , 14 J.L. Econ. & Org. 114 (1998) (presenting a model of judicial review of agency decision making, in which “process review” under the APA for arbitrariness forces agencies to expend resources to reduce the risk of judicial reversal); Emerson H. Tiller & Pablo T. Spiller, Strategic Instruments: Legal Structure and Political Games in Administrative Law , 15 J.L. Econ. & Org . 349 (1999) (finding that agencies choose among “instruments of decision making” so as to increase costs of court review). For an account of executive agency efforts to avoid CBA review by OIRA, see Jennifer Nou , Agency Self-Insulation Under Presidential Review , 126 Harv . L. Rev . 1755 (2013).

The decision provoked unusual agreement among legal commentators—all negative See Robert B. Ahdieh , Reanalyzing Cost-Benefit Analysis: Toward a Framework of Function(s) and Form(s) , 88 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1983 (2013); James D. Cox & Benjamin J.C. Baucom , The Emperor Has No Clothes: Confronting the D.C. Circuit’s Usurpation of SEC Rulemaking Authority , 90 Tex. L. Rev. 1811 (2012); Jill E. Fisch , The Long Road Back: Business Roundtable and the Future of SEC Rulemaking , 36 Seattle U. L. Rev. 695 (2013); Grant M. Hayden & Matthew T. Bodie , The Bizarre Law & Economics of Business Roundtable v. SEC, 38 J. Corp. L. 101 (2012); Kraus & Raso , supra note 12; Michael E. Murphy, The SEC and the District of Columbia Circuit: The Emergency of a Distinct Standard of Judicial Review , 7 Va. L. & Bus. Rev. 125 (2012); Comment, D.C. Circuit Finds SEC Proxy Access Rule Arbitrary and Capricious for Inadequate Economic Analysis , 125 Harv . L. Rev. 1088 (2012); Anthony W. Mongone , Note, Business Roundtable : A New Level of Judicial Scrutiny and Its Implications in a Post-Dodd-Frank World , 2012 Colum. Bus. L. Rev. 746; Stephanie Lyn Parker, Note, The Folly of Rule 14a-11: Business Roundtable v. SEC and the Commission’s Next Step , 61 Am . U. L. Rev. 715 (2012); J. Robert Brown, Jr., Shareholder Access and Uneconomic Economic Analysis: Business Roundtable v. SEC ( Univ. of Denver Sturm College of Law Legal Research Paper Series, Working Paper No. 11-14, 2011), http:// http://www.denverlawreview.org/online-articles/2011/9/30 /shareholder-access-and-uneconomic-economic-analysis-business.html [http://perma.cc/PD72-8K83]; Dennis Kelleher, Stephen Hall & Katelynn Bradley, Setting the Record Straight on Cost-Benefit Analysis and Financial Reform at the SEC , Better Markets, Inc. 59-68 (2012), http://www.bettermarkets.com/sites/default/files/Setting%20The%20Record %20Straight.pdf [http://perma.cc/X4L8-SUK5]. The only substantial defense of the decision is in the CCMC report, CCMC Report , supra note 6, which, as noted above, was funded by a party to the case, the U.S. Chamber of Commerce. Id. at ii.

Indeed, the circumstances were so limited that prominent corporate law scholars labeled the rule “insignificant” Marcel Kahan & Edward Rock, The Insignificance of Proxy Access , 97 Va. L. Rev. 1347 (2011). The CCMR report’s characterization of the proxy access rule as “more substantive,” CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 7, than the CFTC registration and reporting requirements upheld in Investment Company Institute v. CFTC , 891 F. Supp. 2d 162 (2012), is mysterious. Proxy access would not have changed “substantive” corporate governance but only added disclosure and process requirements for proxy solicitation; it would have been, in effect, a cross-subsidy of large, long-term shareholders’ disclosure obligations, but would not have altered voting rights or the relative authority of boards or shareholders to make decisions for corporations.

Bus Roundtable v. SEC, 647 F.3d 1144 (D.C. Cir. 2011).

Id at 1148 .

Id The court also asserted the SEC had been arbitrary by using “inconsistent” estimates of the frequency with which the rule would be used. Id. at 1153. To support this, the court claimed that the SEC had “predicted nominating shareholders would realize ‘direct cost savings’ from not having to print or mail their own proxy materials,” that the SEC had cited comment letters in support of this fact, and that one letter reported the rule would be frequently used, suggesting that the SEC believed that the cost savings would be large. Id. at 1153-54 (noting that the SEC “then cited comment letters predicting the number of elections contested under [the rule] would be quite high” and that “[ o]ne of the comments reported . . . that . . . ‘hundreds’ of . . . companies . . . expected a shareholder . . . to nominate a director using the rule” (citing Letter from Kenneth L. Altman, President, The Altman Grp ., Inc., to Elizabeth M. Murphy, Secretary, Sec. & Exch. Comm’n (Jan. 19, 2010), http://www .sec.gov/comments/s7-10-09/s71009-605.pdf [http://perma.cc/QTJ4-TADN] )). The court’s opinion on this point is egregiously misleading: it falsely claims the SEC relied on the Altman comment as a basis for the SEC’s views on costs, and it then falsely claims that the SEC’s supposed view on costs contradicted other statements in the SEC’s release. In fact, the SEC did not cite any public comments to support its beliefs about direct cost savings, which were qualitative, a matter of common sense, and did not need such support. See Facilitating Shareholder Director Nominations, Exchange Act Release No. 33-9136, 75 Fed. Reg. 56,668 (Sept. 16, 2010). To the contrary, the SEC specifically rejected the claim that the rule would be frequently used, as claimed in the Altman letter cited by the court. Id. at 270. Nowhere does the SEC cite the Altman letter to support its conclusions. Id.

Bus Roundtable , 647 F.3d at 1149-50.

Id at 1153.

Jess Bravin , Why DC. Circuit, at Center of Nominee Fight, Is So Important , Wall St. J., Nov. 20, 2013, http://online.wsj.com/news/articles /SB10001424052702304607104579210383151449004 [http://perma.cc/C5V-Q7UH].

Bus Roundtable , 647 F.3d at 1151.

Chamber of Commerce v SEC, 412 F.3d 133, 143 (D.C. Cir. 2005) (emphasis added).

Stilwell v Office of Thrift Supervision, 569 F.3d 514, 519 (D.C. Cir. 2009) (emphasis added). Nothing in the text of the securities laws would change this; the word “efficiency” does not by any reasonable reading imply a burden to generate evidence that does not exist, and the court in Business Roundtable did not examine the legislative history of the requirement that the SEC consider “efficiency.” See Murphy, supra note 116, at 128-30 ; Mongone , supra note 116, at 746-56.

On the partisan nature of the Court’s decisions on CBA, see the discussion in the text accompanying notes 7 and 8; see also Cass R Sunstein & Adrian Vermeule , Libertarian Administrative Law , 81 U. Chi. L. Rev. (forthcoming 2015) (manuscript at 56) (on file with author) (noting the libertarian ideology of judges on the D.C. Circuit who have been most active in striking down agency decisions on CBA grounds, and that while this ideology does not perfectly track party affiliation, it “correlates powerfully” with it). While the D.C. Circuit now has seven active judges who were nominated by Democratic presidents and four active judges who were nominated by Republican presidents, it also has five senior judges who were nominated by Republican presidents and one senior judge who was nominated by a Democratic president. These senior judges are entitled to (and do) carry up to a full caseload. Because panels are composed of three judges, there remains a strong possibility of partisan or ideological panels reviewing independent agency decisions.

Gen Accounting Office , U.S. Gov’t Accountability Office , GAO/GGD-98-30, Unfunded Mandates: Reform Act Has Had Little Effect on Agencies’ Rulemaking Actions 30 (1998), http://www.gao.gov/assets/230/225165.pdf [http://perma.cc/5QFV-5864].

Sherwin, supra note 15, at 27-28 (citing HR. 4818, 108th Cong. (2004); H.R. R ep . N o . 108-472, at 841 (2004); S. 2908, 108th Cong. (2004) (introduced by Sen. Judd Gregg (R-NH)); Consolidated Appropriations Act of 2005, Pub. L. No. 108-447, 118 Stat. 2809 (2004)).

Full Committee Hearing on Sarbanes-Oxley 404: Will the SEC’s and PCAOB’s New Standards Lower Compliance Costs for Small Companies ?: Hearing Before the H Comm. on Small Bus. , 110th Cong. 97 (2007) (statement of Hal Scott, Professor, Harvard Law Sch.) (“That estimate was, we now know, off by a factor of over 48.”) ; accord CCMR Report , supra note 4. As noted in Part III.A, infra , this criticism was mistaken, but has been repeated by the Committee on Capital Markets Regulation in its 2013 report promoting CBA. Id. at 9.

A Balancing Act: Cost, Compliance, and Competitiveness After Sarbanes-Oxley: Hearing Before the Subcomm on Regulatory Affairs of the H. Comm. on Government Reform , 109th Cong. 2 (2006) (statement of Rep. Patrick T. McHenry, Chairman, H. Subcomm . on Regulatory Affairs) (repeating criticism).

Daniel M Gallagher, Comm’r , Sec. & Exch. Comm’n , Remarks Before the Corporate Directors Forum, (Jan. 29, 2013), http://www.sec.gov/News/Speech/Detail/Speech /1365171492142# .VADgc7xdXkZ [http://perma.cc/TV7S-8QW5] (“One example relates to compliance with Section 404 of Sarbanes Oxley, which the Commission estimated would cost on average roughly $91,000 a year to implement.”).

Memorandum from Dan M Berkovitz , Gen. Counsel, U.S. Commodities Futures Trading Comm’n , & Jim Moser, Acting Chief Economist, U.S. Commodities Futures Trading Comm’n , to Rulemaking Teams (Sept. 29, 2010), http://www.cftc.gov/ucm/groups/public /@aboutcftc/documents/file/oig_investigation_041511.pdf [http://perma.cc/M235-EUT2].

Id at Exhibit 1, 2-3 (“[ S] ection 15 does not require the [CFTC] to quantify the costs and benefits of an action. However, the [CFTC] cannot consider the costs and benefits . . . unless they are presented either quantitatively or qualitatively.”). A follow-up memo, in May 2011, required rulemaking teams to “incorporate the principles of Executive Order 13563 . . . to the extent . . . reasonably feasible” in final rulemakings. Memorandum from Dan M. Berkovitz , Gen. Counsel, U.S. Commodities Futures Trading Comm’n , & Andrei Kirilenko , Chief Economist, U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Comm’n , to Rulemaking Teams 1 ( May 13 , 2011 ) http://www.cftc.gov/ucm/groups/public/@aboutcftc/documents /file/oig_investigation_061311.pdf [http://perma.cc/M3SR-VYNW]. In May 2012, the CFTC and OIRA entered into a memorandum of understanding permitting OIRA staff to provide “technical assistance” to CFTC staff during implementation of the Dodd-Frank Act, “particularly with respect” to CBA/FR. Memorandum of Understanding between Office of Info. & Regulatory Affairs and U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Comm’n (2012), http://www .whitehouse.gov/sites/default/files/omb/inforeg/regpol/oira_cftc_mou_2012.pdf [ http://perma.cc/7AJK-3WE8] .

Wall Street Reform: Oversight of Financial Stability and Consumer and Investor Protections: Hearing Before the S Comm. on Banking, Housing, and Urban Affairs , 113th Cong. 21 (2013) (statement of Sen. Crapo).

Office of the Inspector Gen, Sec. & Exch. Comm’n , Report No. 499, Follow-Up Review of Cost-Benefit Analyses in Selected SEC Dodd-Frank Act Rulemakings 1 (2012); Office of the Inspector Gen., U.S. Commodity Futures Trading Comm’n , A Review of Cost-Benefit Analyses Performed by the Commodity Futures Trading Commission in Connection with Rulemakings Undertaken Pursuant to the Dodd-Frank Act, at i (2011).

Pub L. No. 112-10, § 1573(a), 125 Stat. 38, 138-39 (2011) (codified at 12 U.S.C. § 5496(b)).

US. Gov’t Accountability Office, GAO-12-151, Dodd -Frank Act Regulations: Implementation Could Benefit from Additional Analyses and Coordination 14 (2011).

Id at 16-17. In 2012, the GAO released another report advocating CBA/FR, reiterating its view that financial regulators should “more fully incorporate OMB’s guidance into their rulemaking policies.” U.S. Gov’t Accountability Office, GAO-13-101, Dodd-Frank Act: Agencies’ Efforts To Analyze and Coordinate Their Rules (2012) (text on “highlights” page).

US. Gov’t Accountability Office , supra note 138, at 17.

See CCMC Report , supra note 6, at 9-10 ; CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 7-10 Neither the GAO nor other CBA proponents have set out examples of how the SEC should conduct CBA/FR, limiting themselves to simply counting what share of rulemakings contained CBA/FR of any kind, and what share contained at least some quantification, without regard to whether the quantification is precise, reliable, or comprehensive as to either costs or benefits. The CCMR report holds up one SEC rulemaking as the “gold-standard” of CBA/FR, CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 13-15, as discussed infra at text accompanying notes 344-361.

Eg. , Who Is Too Big To Fail? GAO’s Assessment of the Financial Stability Oversight Council and the Office of Financial Research : Hearing Before the Subcomm . on Oversight and Investigations of the H. Comm. on Fin. Serv ., 113th Cong. 26 (2013) (question from Rep. Wagner to witness from Financial Stability Oversight Council about a “GAO report that talked about [needing] a [CBA]”).

Memorandum from the Div of Risk, Strategy and Fin. Innovation and the Office of the Gen. Counsel, U.S. Sec. & Exch. Comm’n , to the Staff of the Rulemaking Div. and Offices, U.S. Sec. & Exch. Comm’n , on Current Guidance on Economic Analysis in SEC Rulemakings 1 (2012), http://www.sec.gov/divisions/riskfin/rsfi_guidance_econ_analy_secrulemaking.pdf [http://perma.cc/RDN3-NU64].

Id at 4-15. See sources cited supra notes 20 and 81 (citing CBA Executives Orders and OMB Guidance).

S 1173, 113th Cong. (2013). The Senators were Senators Collins (R-ME), Portman (R-OH), and Warner (D-VA). A similar bill was introduced in 2012. S. 3468, 112th Cong. (2012). Other bills promoting CBA have been introduced in this and prior years. E.g ., Unfunded Mandates Information and Transparency Act of 2014, H.R. 899, 113th Cong. (2014); Regulatory Sunset and Review Act of 2013, H.R. 309, 113th Cong. (2013); Startup Act 3.0, S. 310, 113th Cong. (2013); SEC Regulatory Accountability Act, H.R. 1062, 113th Cong. (2013); Startup Act 3.0, H.R. 714, 113th Cong. (2013); Congressional Office of Regulatory Analysis Creation and Sunset and Review Act of 2011, H.R. 214, 112th Cong. (2011); Regulatory Improvement Act of 1999, S. 746, 106th Cong. (1999); Regulatory Improvement Act of 1998, S. 981, 105th Cong. (1997); Comprehensive Regulatory Reform Act of 1995, S. 343, 104th Cong. (1995); Regulatory Reform and Relief Act, H.R. 926, 104th Cong. (1995). To date, a small number of former commissioners of independent agencies have backed the bill. E.g ., Letter to the Chair and Ranking Member of the Senate Homeland Sec. and Gov’t Affairs Comm., June 18, 2013, http://www.portman.senate.gov/public/index .cfm/files/serve ?File _id=6f3f466c-e744-4d99-892a-91f6e6348ebf [http://perma.cc/9V34-W5X9].

S 1173, § 3(a)(6). The independent financial regulatory agencies include, among others, the Bureau of Consumer Financial Protection (CFPB), Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC), Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), Federal Reserve System, Federal Housing Finance Agency (FHFA), Federal Trade Commission (FTC), Office of the Comptroller of the Currency (OCC), Office of Financial Research (OFR), and Securities Exchange Commission (SEC). S. 1173, § 2(4) (incorporating 44 U.S.C. § 3502(5) (2012)). The newly created CFPB and OFR were added to the list in the Dodd-Frank Act, § 1100D, and the OCC was added to the list in § 315 of that Act. Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1524 (codified in scattered sections).

S 1173, § 2(5) (incorporating the definition of “rule” under 5 U.S.C. § 551 (2012), which defines a “rule” as any “statement of general or particular applicability and future effect designed to implement, interpret, or prescribe law or policy”).

Id § 3(c)(3)(B).

See Alan B Morrison, The Administrative Procedure Act: A Living and Responsive Law , 72 Va. L. Rev . 253, 256 (1986) (“[ R] ulemakings are often more controversial than adjudications [under the APA], whose very processes are hidden from outsiders.”).

See CCMR Report, supra note 4, at 1 (stating that CBA/FR should “[ f] ocus on economically significant rules”)

It is worth noting that no similar efforts can be found in the more prominent publications advocating CBA/FR of financial regulation E.g. , CCMC Report , supra note 6; CCMR Report , supra note 4. The closest proponents come is to point to selected CBA/FR as “gold standard” CBA/FR, but CBA/FR advocates do not review that CBA in any detail, and as discussed in Part III.E below, these “gold standards” are no more compelling in their guesstimated CBA/FR components than the examples reviewed here. This gap between what the CBA/FR proponents promise can be done and what they can demonstrate has been done is troubling.

This section draws extensively on John C Coates IV & Suraj Srinivasan , SOX After Ten Years: A Multidisciplinary Review, 29 Acct. Horizons (forthcoming 2015), http://ssrn.com/abstract=2379731 [http://perma.cc/6SVZ-ELZW].

For a review and evaluation of the core elements of SOX, see John C Coates IV, The Goals and Promise of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act , 21 J. Econ. Persp . 91 (2007).

Such systems consist of methods by companies that monitor use of the company’s assets and produce accurate financial reports, including (for example) computer programs designed to detect inconsistencies between customer orders and accounting records, rules for which corporate agents can authorize certain expenditures and transactions, internal audits, and verification procedures See Commission Guidance Regarding Management’s Report on Internal Control Over Financial Reporting, Exchange Act Release Nos. 33-8810, 34-55929, 72 Fed. Reg. 35,324 (June 27, 2007).

Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 § 3(a), 107 Pub L. No. 204, 116 Stat. 745, 749 (codified at 15 U.S.C. 7202 (2012)).

Management’s Report on Internal Control Over Financial Reporting and Certification of Disclosure in Exchange Act Periodic Reports, 68 Fed Reg 36,636 (June 18, 2003) (codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 210, 228, 229, 240, 249, 270, 274). For brevity, I refer to the SEC’s “rule” in this section, although in fact the release modified a number of separate SEC rules. The effect of the SEC’s rules in practice would turn out to be heavily influenced by rules separately adopted by the PCAOB.

See supra notes 77-78, 87-88, 95-98 and accompanying text

This was required by the National Securities Markets Improvement Act of 1996, Pub L. No. 104-290, 110 Stat. 3416, 3424-25 (codified in scattered sections of 15 U.S.C.), which amended three of the SEC’s governing statutes—the Securities Act of 1933, the Exchange Act of 1934, and the Investment Company Act of 1940—to require the SEC to consider whether any rulemaking done “pursuant to” those statutes would “promote efficiency, competition, and capital formation.” 15 U.S.C. §§ 77b(b), 78c(f), 80a-2(c) (2012).

See supra notes 81-82

68 Fed Reg. 36,636, 36,656-57 (June 18, 2003).

Id at 36,657.

Management’s Report on Internal Control Over Financial Reporting and Certification of Disclosure in Exchange Act Periodic Reports, Exchange Act Release Nos 33-8238, 34-47986, Investment Company Act Release No. IC-26068 at pt. V( B) & n.174 (Aug. 14, 2003), http://www.sec.gov/rules/final/33-8238.htm [http://perma.cc/XZN4-GMZ5] (“The estimate does not include the costs of the auditor’s attestation report, which many commenters have suggested might be substantial.”).

Full Committee Hearing on Sarbanes-Oxley Section 404: Will the SEC’s and PCAOB’s New Standards Lower Compliance Costs for Small Companies ?: Hearing Before the H Comm. on Small Bus. , 110th Cong. 97 (2007) (statement of Hal S. Scott, Dir., Comm. on Capital Mkts . Regulation) (“[The SEC’s] estimate was, we now know, off by a factor of over 48.”). Presumably, this claim is based on comparing the SEC’s cost estimate with the results of a survey ( n =274) conducted by the Financial Executives International (FEI) and Financial Executives Research Foundation (FERF). That survey found the average cost of SOX 404 reported in 2004 was $4.4 million (4,400,000 / 91,000 = 48.4). FEI is a trade group, and the FERF is a related organization that performs research on topics of interest to chief finance officers of large companies and other members. The FEI/FERF study is formally titled Financial Executives International and Financial Executives Research Foundation , Special Survey on Sarbanes-Oxley Section 404 Implementation (2005) [hereinafter FEI/FERF Survey ].

Criticisms of the SEC’s cost estimate are misplaced for two other reasons The FEI/FERF survey, see supra note 166, was of large firms (average revenues of $6 billion, as compared to overall average revenues for all public firms in Compustat in 2004 of $2 billion, and median revenues for such firms of $96 million). Since compliance costs generally, and control system costs in particular, increase at a decreasing rate in relation to firm size, $4.4 million would have been too high as an average for all covered firms even in 2004. In addition, the FEI/FERF estimate was based on data that was gathered from companies during their first year under the rule. The costs of any new rule will fall over time, with learning, as has been the case with SOX 404. Further, the agency ultimately charged with supervising section 404(b) work by audit firms, the PCAOB, modified the requirements applicable under that section in 2007, further dramatically reducing the costs of the rule. The upshot is that the best current estimate of section 404 costs is closer to $400,000 than to $4.4 million—still higher than the SEC’s estimate of section 404(a) costs, but reasonably close, once one acknowledges that the $91,000 estimate was for a part and not all of section 404’s costs.

See Coates & Srinivasan , supra note 155, at 25

See Management’s Report on Internal Control Over Financial Reporting and Certification of Disclosure in Exchange Act Periodic Reports, supra note 165, at pt V( B).

See supra note 166

See infra text accompanying notes 182-203

See Amendments to Rules Regarding Management’s Report on Internal Control Over Financial Reporting, 72 Fed Reg. 35,310 (June 27, 2007) (codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 210, 228, 229, 240); Internal Control Over Financial Reporting in Exchange Act Periodic Reports of Non-Accelerated Filers and Newly Public Companies, 71 Fed. Reg. 76,580 (Dec. 21, 2006) (codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 210, 228, 229, 240, 249).

Section 3(e) of Executive Order 12,866, supra note 81, defines the “regulatory action” covered by the order to include “any substantive action by an agency . . that promulgates or is expected to lead to the promulgation of a final rule or regulation,” without regard to whether the final rule adds new restrictions on private activity or exempts private activity covered by a prior regulation. Exec. Order 12,866, 58 Fed. Reg. 51,735 (Sept. 30, 1993).

See CCMC Report, supra note 6 ; CCMR Report , supra note 4

Throughout this section, I use “fraud” in a loose sense, and mean it to encompass deceptive, manipulative, or misleading accounting and other financial disclosures that could be prevented or corrected in a cost-effective manner, regardless of whether proof of specific intent to deceive, reasonable reliance, or other elements of the tort or crime of fraud exists, and regardless of whether the accounting technically complies with generally accepted accounting principles

See Coates & Srinivasan , supra note 155

Id at 46. Interestingly, the U.S. crime victimization survey does not ask questions that would be likely to elicit data on fraud incidence, instead focusing on violent crime, sexual assaults, and stalking. See Census Bureau, OMB No. 1121-0111, National Crime Victimization Survey: NCVS-1 Basic Screen Questionnaire , U.S. Dep’t Commerce, http://www.bjs.gov/content/pub/pdf/ncvs1_2012.pdf [http://perma.cc/Q8BM-N3WU]; Census Bureau, OMB No. 1121-0302, Supplemental Victimization Survey , U.S. Dep’t Commerce (2006), http://www.bjs.gov/content/pub/pdf/svs1_06.pdf [http://perma.cc/RJ8H-XYUN]. Identity theft and cyber crimes are types of fraud surveyed by the Bureau of Justice Statistics, see Erika Harrell & Lynn Langton , Bureau of Justice Statistics, U.S. Dep’t Justice, Victims of Identity Theft, 2012, ( Dec. 2013), http://www.bjs.gov/content/pub/pdf/vit12.pdf [http://perma.cc/DDX4-HWPU]; Bureau of Justice Statistics , Cybercrime , U.S. Dep’t Justice, http://www.bjs.gov/index.cfm ?ty =tp&tid=41 [http://perma.cc/9LWR-VJTY], but no general survey of fraud is conducted by the Bureau of Justice Statistics.

See Jonathan S Feinstein, Detection Controlled Estimation , 33 J.L. & Econ. 233 , 233-34 (1990).

Eg. , Vikramaditya S. Khanna et al., CEO Connectedness and Corporate Frauds , J. Fin. ( forthcoming 2015), http://ssrn.com/abstract=2323251 [http://perma.cc/S3YL-ZKBM]; Si Li, Corporate Financial Fraud: An Application of Detection Controlled Estimation (Sch. of Bus. and Econ., Wilfrid Laurier Univ., Working Paper, July 2013), http://ssrn.com/abstract=1698038 [http://perma.cc/WB8G-ZRNZ]; Tracy Yue Wang, Corporate Securities Fraud: An Economic Analysis (Carlson Sch. of Mgmt., Univ. of Minn., Working Paper, Apr. 2006), http://home.business.utah.edu/finea/paper1-theory.pdf [http://perma.cc/AW9P-33SF]. Such models have their weaknesses, as they rely in an ad hoc fashion on different instruments that are assumed to be exogenous, when none truly are exogenous; they are, however, the best that researchers have yet devised.

IJ. Alexander Dyck et al., How Pervasive Is Corporate Fraud? 4 ( Rotman Sch. of Mgmt. Working Paper No. 222608, Feb. 2013), http://ssrn.com/abstract=2222608 [http://perma.cc/D7H6-G47F]. They validate this measure with a survey of fraud observed by business school students at former employers. Id. at 21-23.

For related research, using different and less theoretically grounded empirical methods, see Anastasia K Zakolyukina , Measuring Intentional GAAP Violations: A Structural Approach (Univ. of Chicago Booth Sch. of Bus ., Working Paper No. 13-45, Apr. 25, 2014), http://ssrn.com/abstract=2242251 [http://perma.cc/X4QR-4JSC] which estimates undetected intended earnings manipulation from a sample of 1400 CEOs after SOX. She finds the probability of detection is six percent and that intended earnings manipulation generates a loss of twenty-four percent to a firm’s CEO wealth when detected. The inference she draws is that seventy-three percent of her sample has incentives to manipulate earnings, and that the value-weighted bias in stock prices is 2.82%. Id. at 3. A survey-based study is provided in Ilia Dichev et al., Earnings Quality: Evidence from the Field , 56 J. Acct. & Econ . 1, 30 (2013), in which respondents suggest around twenty percent of firms exploit GAAP to misrepresent reported performance in their financial statements.

Assume, for example, a fraudster obtains $1 from a victim and spends it on food Is the social loss $0 or $1? If the criminal’s utility is ignored and the fraud has no effect besides the transfer of $1, the social loss is $1. If the criminal’s utility is counted equally with the victim’s, and neither attaches unusual utility to the dollar, the social loss is $0.

For example, David A Anderson, The Aggregate Burden of Crime , 42 J.L. & Econ. 611, 629 tbl.7 (1999 ), estimates that such gains, if counted, roughly double the costs of crime.

OMB Guidance, supra note 20

In the context of crime, compare Philip J Cook, Crime Statistics: Costs of Crime , in 1 Encyclopedia of Crime and Justice 373 (Sanford H. Kadish et al. eds ., 1983) (criminals’ utility should count) with Mark A. Cohen, The Costs of Crime and Justice (2005) (criminals’ utility should not count), and The Cost of Crime: Understanding the Financial and Human Impact of Criminal Activity: Hearing Before the S. Comm. on the Judiciary , 109th Cong. 7 (2006) (statement of Jens Ludwig, Professor, Georgetown Public Policy Institute) (same).

Fraud is criminalized in part because it causes large externalities: direct remediable civil damages are not thought to be large enough to provide sufficient incentive for private actors to enforce optimally S. Shavell , The Judgment Proof Problem , 6  Int’l Rev. L. & Econ . 45 (1986) (tort- feasors may be “judgment proof” against large civil sanctions). But criminal sanctions are reserved for a small subset of frauds—those in which clear evidence is available ex post for frauds caused by individuals with specific intent—and the nature of fraud is such that this type of evidence is often unavailable. Section 24 of the Securities Act of 1933 imposes criminal liability for “willful” violations. Securities Act of 1933, ch. 38, § 24, 48 Stat. 74 (codified at 15 U.S.C. § 77x (2012));  see also Securities Exchange Act of 1934, 15 U.S.C. § 78a (2012).

Baruch Lev, Corporate Earnings: Facts and Fiction , 17 J Econ. Persp . 27, 42-44 (2003). Anderson, supra note 183, at 616-17, 629, presents a similar list of indirect effects of crime generally. He estimates the indirect costs—what he categorizes as “crime-induced production,” opportunity costs, and risks to life and health—as roughly double the value of victim-to-criminal property transfers, and when he counts the costs incurred by criminals, the total costs of crime are more than double the value of those transfers. Id. at 629 tbl.7. In other words, the external effects of crime generally greatly exceed their direct effects.

Reduced quality of financial information provided by one firm will in the first instance lower expectations of the quality of information provided by other firms, heighten expected fraud-related losses generally, and reduce confidence in public securities markets and in markets more generally Market-wide liquidity deteriorated following Enron and related scandals, and improved after SOX’s adoption. Pankaj K. Jain et al., The Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 and Market Liquidity , 43 Fin . Rev. 361 (2008). Mariassunta Giannetti and Tracy Yue Wang show that revelation of corporate frauds in a state caused equity holdings of households in that state to fall, increasing the cost of capital for non-fraudulent firms. Mariassunta Giannetti & Tracy Yue Wang, Corporate Scandals and Household Stock Market Participation (Eur. Corp. Governance Inst., Finance Working Paper No. 405/2014, 2014), http://ssrn.com/abstract=2331588 [http://perma.cc/73LY-VSWS]. For a more general study of the effect of trust on finance, see Luigi Guiso et al., Trusting the Stock Market , 63 J. Fin. 2557 (2008). See also Emilia Bonaccorsi di Patti, Weak Institutions and Credit Availability: The Impact of Crime on Bank Loans (Bank of It., Occasional Paper No. 52, 2009), http://ssrn.com/abstract=1606242 [http://perma.cc/84L3-UWXL] (demonstrating that crime, including fraud, increases borrowing costs and increases capital constraints by the public generally).

Misallocation is caused by fraudulent signals of the value of firms or whole industries, as in the telecom and Internet bubbles For a review of studies showing that corporate finance decisions are driven by capital market prices, including prices that deviate from fundamental values (that is, mispricing), see Malcolm Baker, Capital Market-Driven Corporate Finance , 1 Ann. Rev. Fin. Econ 181 (2009). See also Malcolm Baker et al., When Does the Market Matter? Stock Prices and the Investment of Equity-Dependent Firms , Q. J. Econ. 969 (2003) (modeling and presenting evidence that bubbles affect corporate investment). Simi Kedia and Thomas Philippon model investment decisions of firms during periods of fraud and find empirical support for their prediction that fraud and earnings management distort hiring and investment decisions of firms, leading to over-investment and excessive hiring during periods of suspicious accounting; this over-investment and excessive hiring, in turn, lead to misallocation of resources in the economy. Simi Kedia & Thomas Philippon , The Economics of Fraudulent Accounting , 22 Rev. Fin . Stud. 2169 (2009).

One can view costly acquisitions by fraudulent companies of other companies as an example of the prior category (misallocated resources), but it is important enough to warrant estimating separately Such acquisitions are often followed by mismanagement or outright theft, contributing to otherwise avoidable bankruptcies. While bankruptcy can reorganize firms, resulting in transfers among investors, they also use up real resources. For a model of merger and acquisition activity driven by mispricing, see Andrei Shleifer & Robert W. Vishny , Stock Market Driven Acquisitions , 70 J. Fin. Econ. 295 (2003). For estimates of the costs of bankruptcy, see, for example, Arturo Bris et al., The Costs of Bankruptcy: Chapter 7 Liquidation Versus Chapter 11 Reorganization , 61 J. Fin. 1253 (2006), which estimates that the range of firm assets resulting from formal bankruptcy is between two and twenty percent.

Such costs include bonding and monitoring by investors to avoid fraud, such as for audit firms, independent directors, appraisers, analysts, regulatory and enforcement agencies, and prisons Audit fees were rising prior to SOX, due to market-driven demand for increased scrutiny of financial statements following the scandals that led to SOX. Sharad Asthana et al., The Effect of Enron, Andersen, and Sarbanes-Oxley on the US Market for Audit Services , 22 Acct. Res. J. 4 (2009). Likewise, separate from SOX, the New York Stock Exchange and the Nasdaq adopted tighter corporate governance requirements in response to Enron et al., which tightened the criteria for and likely increased the costs of recruiting independent directors. See Coates, supra note 156, at 111.

These third parties include those dependent on the victims of the initial fraud (eg., family, business partners, creditors, and communities). For studies showing spillover effects of restatements, see Coates & Srinivasan , supra note 155, at 51 n.21.

While SOX 404 would have had no effect on Madoff’s scheme, since he kept his brokerage private and outside the scope of SOX, the findings are suggestive of what might be discovered if the prospect of quantifying such harms to fraud victims more generally were undertaken For the number of investors affected, see Trustee’s Ninth Interim Report for the Period Ending March 31, 2013, exhibit A at 4-5, Sec. Investor Prot. Corp. v. Bernard L. Madoff Inv. Sec. ( In re Bernard L. Madoff ), No. 08-01789 ( Bankr . S.D.N.Y. Apr. 30, 2013). For charities harmed by the Madoff scandal, see Anthony Weiss & Gabrielle Birkner , Charities, Day Schools Hard Hit by Madoff Scandal , Jewish Daily Forward (Dec. 17, 2008), http://forward.com/articles/14729/charities-day-schools-hard-hit-by-madoff-scandal [http://perma.cc/AZ7D-CPRA].

See Trustee’s Ninth Interim Report, supra note 194, exhibit A at 2

Audrey Freshman, Financial Disaster as a Risk Factor for Posttraumatic Stress Disorder: Internet Survey of Trauma in Victims of the Madoff Ponzi Scheme , 37 Health & Soc Work 39, 44-47 (2012).

Carol Graham et al, The Bigger They Are, the Harder They Fall: An Estimate of the Costs of the Crisis in Corporate Governance (The Brookings Inst., Working Paper, 2002), http://www.brookings.edu/views/papers/graham/20020722Graham.pdf [http://perma.cc/MK3C-MWDY] . Another attempt to assess the size of externalities (without quantifying them for society overall) uses brokerage data of a sample of retail investors across the United States and shows that, upon the revelation of fraud in a company in a particular state, all households in the state, not just the ones owning stocks of fraud firms, reduce their equity holdings. Giannetti & Wang, supra note 189.

This is the model described in David Reifschneider et al, Aggregate Disturbances, Monetary Policy, and the Macroeconomy : The FRB/US Perspective , 85 Fed. Res. Bull. 1 (1999 ), sometimes referred to as the “FRB/US” (pronounced “ ferbus ”) model. See Div. of Research & Statistics, Fed. Reserve Bd. , A Guide to FRB/US: A Macroeconomic Model of the United States (Flint Brayton & Peter Tinsley eds ., Oct. 1996), http://www.federalreserve .gov/pubs/feds/1996/199642/199642pap.pdf [http://perma.cc/H6LF-TC2Q].

Graham et al, supra note 197, at 5.

The sensitivity of estimates of social harms to assumptions in similar macroeconomic models is discussed more in connection with the Basel III rules in Part IIIC, infra .

For overviews, see John J Donohue III, Assessing the Relative Benefits of Incarceration : Overall Changes and the Benefits on the Margin , in Do Prisons Make Us Safer? The Benefits and Costs of The Prison Boom 269, 270-341 (Steven Raphael & Michael A. Stoll eds ., 2009); and Jens Ludwig, The Costs of Crime , 9 Criminology & Pub. Pol’y 307, 307-11 (2010).

See John P Hoehn et al., A Hedonic Model of Interregional Wages, Rents and Amenity Values , 27 J. Regional Sci . 605 (1987); Richard Thaler , A Note on the Value of Crime Control: Evidence from the Property Market , 5 J. Urb . Econ . 137 (1978).

See Mark A Cohen et al., Willingness-to-Pay for Crime Control Programs , 42 Criminology 89 (2004); Daniel S. Nagin et al., Public Preferences for Rehabilitation Versus Incarceration of Juvenile Offenders: Evidence from a Contingent Valuation Survey , 5 Criminology & Pub. Pol’y 627 (2006).

See Anderson, supra note 183, at 616-29

See Simon Moore & Jonathan P Shepherd, The Cost of Fear: Shadow Pricing the Intangible Costs of Crime , 38 Applied Econ. 293 (2006).

These methods are probably best used in combination, as described in Donohue, supra note 202, at 321 (“Instead of trying to resolve these normative questions, this chapter illustrates their importance by presenting various estimates of the cost of crime based on different assumptions The effort to highlight the underlying assumptions and methodologies will enable readers to implement their own normative choices in conducting cost-benefit analyses of incarceration.”).

Peter A Diamond & Jerry A. Hausman , Contingent Valuation: Is Some Number Better than No Number ? , 8 J. Econ. Persp . 45, 63 (1994) (concluding that “survey responses [in contingent valuation surveys] are not satisfactory bases for policy” because they are internally inconsistent, unreliable and biased by such factors as the “warm glow” from answering questions in particular ways); see also John Bronsteen et al., Well-Being Analysis vs. Cost-Benefit Analysis , 62 Duke L.J . 1603 (2013) (advocating use of hedonic surveys as more reliable than willingness-to-pay surveys, which are conventionally used in CBA in the non-financial regulatory context).

See Coates & Srinivasan , supra note 155, at 17

See, eg. , Ehud Kamar et al., Going-Private Decisions and the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002: A Cross-Country Analysis , 25 J.L. Econ. & Org. 107 (2009) (studying whether SOX drove firms out of the public capital market) ; see also Coates & Srinivasan , supra note 155, at 55 (touting difference-in-difference studies).

This seems to have been true in some of the earliest studies of the effects of SOX, which found differences in US. firms after SOX compared to Canadian or U.K. firms. For a selection of these studies, see Coates & Srinivasan , supra note 155, at 29-31. Those differences, however, either started well before SOX, or affected U.S. firms not subject to SOX as much as they did U.S. firms subject to SOX, such that no consensus has emerged as to whether SOX had the studied effects. Id.

See the studies reviewed in Coates and Srinivasan , supra note 155, at 27, 30, 56

One could imagine a law like SOX 404 applying to all firms with a past (and so not easily manipulated) market capitalization of between $75 million and $100 million, or between $100 million and $125 million, or between $150 million and $175 million, and so on all the way through the full distribution of market capitalizations Needless to say, even though it may be the only way to derive reliable estimates of the aggregate social costs and benefits of the rule, sch a novel regulatory design would likely generate protest from covered companies, who would rightly complain that they compete with the exempt companies in the product, labor, and capital markets and that they were being potentially disadvantaged by any regulatory costs the rule might impose.

Peter Iliev , The Effect of SOX Section 404: Costs, Earnings Quality, and Stock Prices , 65 J Fin . 1163 (2010).

Coates & Srinivasan , supra note 153 .

Stefan Arping & Zacharias Sautner , Did SOX Section 404 Make Firms Less Opaque? Evidence from Cross-Listed Firms , 30 Contemp Acct. Res. 1133 (2013); Christian Leuz et al., Why Do Firms Go Dark? Causes and Economic Consequences of Voluntary SEC Deregistrations , 45 J. Acct. & Econ. 181 (2008).

At first pass, it might seem that the dual effects of this choice on both costs and benefits would cancel out as long as the choices were consistent, but in fact that would require a further debatable assumption—that is, that the functional relationship between actual legal compliance on the rule’s effects is the same for both costs and benefits That assumption seems at least possibly mistaken, because (for example) the extra costs from assuming a realistic baseline should be larger for larger companies, but they should increase at a decreasing rate in relation to firm size. On the other hand, the extra benefits might not follow that pattern, and in fact might increase at an increasing rate, if (for example) large firm frauds (as at Enron) have externalities that are not only larger than externalities of smaller firms, but also larger by a multiple greater than one due to informational cascades and threshold effects in how the media report on frauds.

Another open issue for CBA/FR is whether to use a national or supranational unit of analysis for purposes of estimating welfare effects If, for example, SOX 404 prevented fraud by U.S.-listed but foreign-based companies that harms foreign investors, should that count as a social gain? What if, as some studies suggest, e.g. , Coates & Srinivasan , supra note 155, SOX 404 reduced cross-listings in the U.S. of foreign firms but with an effect that was concentrated among the most fraud-prone firms? If the result was to shift sales of stock by fraud-prone companies from the U.S. to other countries but not to reduce the total amount of fraud, should that count as a “benefit” for CBA/FR purposes under U.S. law? A similar unresolved issue concerns the costs of the rule: if the shift of firms from the U.S. to foreign stock markets harmed the New York economy but benefited the London or Hong Kong economies, should the losses count in a CBA/FR of the rule? The authors of the CCMR report seem to think such losses to the U.S. economy should count as “costs” under CBA. CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 10 (criticizing the SEC for not attempting to measure whether new rules “would . . . deter foreign companies from tapping U.S. capital markets”). But that report does not defend the position and does not take the correlative position that an increase in larger company cross-listings (for example, by lowering the cost of capital relative to foreign jurisdictions by reducing information asymmetries) should count as a benefit (and if a benefit, whether it should be a gross benefit to the United States or net of lower benefits to the issuers’ home countries). Neither the CFTC’s nor the SEC’s governing statutes specify the United States as the governing unit when commanding those agencies to consider “costs and benefits” or “efficiency,” respectively. See sources cited supra note 6.

See Harrington et al, supra note 34, for evidence of this outside the financial context.

See FEI/FERF Survey , supra note 166

See Coates & Srinivasan , supra note 155, at 25-29

SOX 404, for example, generates higher costs for larger firms, as well as for firms with less centralized decision making and more dispersed or fragmented assets Id. To some extent, the RFA and analyses thereunder have produced useful methods of breaking down costs by firm size, but some of the more important differences may have less to do with size and more to do with industry, complexity, or geographic dispersion.

Office of Chief Accountant, Study and Recommendations on Sections 404(b) of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 for Issuers with Public Float Between $75 and $250 Million , Sec & Exch. Commission ( 2011) [hereinafter SEC, Study and Recommendations ], http://www.sec.gov /news/studies/2011/404bfloat-study.pdf [http://perma.cc/L5P7-PSHX]; Office of Econ. Analysis, Study of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act , supra note 64.

See Leonce L Bargeron et al., Sarbanes-Oxley and Corporate Risk-Taking , 49 J. Acct. & Econ. 34 (2010) (finding reduced risk-taking by U.S. companies subject to SOX compared to non-U.S. companies not subject to SOX). But see Ana M. Albuquerque & Julie L. Zhu, Has Section 404 of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act Discouraged Corporate Risk-Taking? New Evidence from a Natural Experiment ( Bos . Univ. Sch. of Mgmt. Research Paper Series, Working Paper No. 2013-6, 2013), http://ssrn.com/abstract=1997228 [http://perma.cc/J88G-TTN9] (finding a trend towards reduced risk-taking by U.S. companies prior to SOX).

The cost estimates range from more than $44 million per year on average (firms with an average of $6 billion in revenues in 2004, based on a FEI/FERF survey) to $350,000 (firms with market capitalizations under $10 billion in 2012, based on a GAO survey). See FEI/FERF Survey, supra note 166; U.S. Gov’t Accountability Office , GAO-13-582, Internal Controls: SEC Should Consider Requiring Companies To Disclose Whether They Obtained an Auditor Attestation 23 (2013).

For one economist’s highly skeptical assessment of IAMs in the environmental context, see Robert S Pindyck , Climate Change Policy: What Do the Models Tell Us ? , 51 J. Econ. Lit. 860 (2013). Pindyck calls for environmental policymaking to be informed by research, including empirical research, but ultimately based not on IAMs or guesstimated CBA but on “simpler” policy approaches that use a “plausible” range of outcomes and probabilities, where “plausible” is what is acceptable to a range of economists and subject matter experts (in his analysis, climate scientists). Id. at 869-70.

PV=C/R , where PV is the present value, C is the annual cost, and R is the discount rate

This is a rough range of per-year, per-firm direct cost estimates reflected in the SEC’s comprehensive survey of such costs in 2007 and 2008 See Office of Econ. Analysis, Study of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act , supra note 64, at 46 tbl.9 (2009). The estimates were reduced by an arbitrary thirty percent to reflect increases that would have occurred without SOX, due to market pressures reacting to Enron and related scandals.

The Office of Management and Budget suggests these discount rates OMB Guidance, supra note 20, at 18. Whether they are appropriate at all, or for assessing financial regulation, is unclear. See Martin L. Weitzman, Tail-Hedge Discounting and the Social Cost of Carbon , 51 J. Econ. Lit. 873 (2013) (critiquing the current discount rate of three percent recommended by OMB and suggesting one percent instead, based on current yields on U.S. Treasuries). If a discount rate of one percent were used instead of three percent, the sensitivity to the net costs and benefits reported in Table 3 below for discount rates would increase by another 852%. One can also argue for discount rates higher than seven percent, depending on what time period one uses to average returns on equity investments. As discussed in Part III.C, two further discount rates (2.5% and 5%) are used by the Bank for International Settlements in its CBA/FR of the Basel III capital rules discussed below, and yet another (3.5%) is used by the FSA in its CBA/FR of the mortgage reforms discussed in Part III.E below. That six different discount rates (1%, 2.5%, 3%, 3.5%, 5%, 7%) are plausible is itself a source of concern about CBA/FR.

See Office of Econ Analysis, Study of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act , supra note 64, at 27 tbl.1 (showing 2205 companies subject to 404(b) that did not answer the survey and 2081 companies subject to 404(b) that did answer the survey, totaling 4286, grossed up to 4400 to reflect growth in the number of listed companies since 2009).

See supra text accompanying note 180

This range is roughly equivalent at the high end to reductions in the shares of US. public companies that were meeting or just beating analyst estimates in the post-SOX period, with the low end being motivated by the likelihood that SOX’s effects on fraud are diminishing over time and/or caused by changes other than SOX 404. Eli Bartov & Daniel A. Cohen, The “Numbers Game” in the Pre- and Post-Sarbanes-Oxley Eras , 24 J. Acct. Auditing & Fin. 505, 517 fig.2 (2009).

This range extends from 50% to 200% of the point estimate of the relationship between transfers and externalities of crime from Anderson, supra note 183, at 629 tbl7.

SEC, Study and Recommendations , supra note 223, at 53-55 ; Office of Econ Analysis, Study of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act , supra note 64.

Another method for estimating the net costs and benefits of a financial regulation is the “event study,” which examines market reactions to events leading up to a regulation’s enactment One estimate of the negative effects of SOX overall, based on stock market reactions to events leading to its passage, was roughly -0.07% of the U.S. equity market capitalization. Ivy Xiying Zhang, Economic Consequences of the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 , 44 J. Acct. & Econ . 74, 92 tbl.2 (2007). That represented a net effect of more than negative $980 billion, based on U.S. equity market capitalization in 2003 (when SOX § 404 was adopted) of roughly $14 trillion. Market Capitalization of Listed Companies , World Bank , http://www.data.worldbank.org/indicator/CM.MKT.LCAP.CD [http://perma.cc/8FYT-9CNM]. By contrast, other studies of the stock market reaction to SOX produced results ranging from positive $420 billion to $1.7 trillion. Aigbe Akhigbe & Anna D. Martin, Valuation Impact of Sarbanes-Oxley: Evidence from Disclosure and Governance Within the Financial Services Industry , 30 J. Banking & Fin. 989 (2006); Pankaj K. Jain & Zabihollah Rezaee , The Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 and Capital-Market Behavior: Early Evidence , 23 Contemp. Acct. Res . 629 (2006) ; Haidan Li et al., Market Reaction to Events Surrounding the Sarbanes-Oxley Act of 2002 and Earnings Management , 51 J.L. & Econ. 111 (2008). The studies were published in peer-reviewed journals, and they included plausible cross-sectional tests of the validity of the estimates. For example, each contrasted differing market reactions to firms that theory would predict to be more or less benefited or harmed by SOX and found results consistent with at least some of those theories.

Fidelity turned out not to be a target of the investigations, but Spitzer did not let that get in the way of a dramatic moment

2006 Performance and Accountability Report , Sec & Exch. Comm’n 23 (2006), http://www.sec.gov/about/secpar/secpar2006.pdf [http://perma.cc/A474-TGZ4] (noting that “fair funds” were established pursuant to SEC enforcement actions concerning market timing and late trading); John C. Coates IV, Reforming the Taxation and Regulation of Mutual Funds: A Comparative Legal and Economic Analysis , 1 J. Legal Analysis 591, 592-93 & n.3 (2009). I served as an independent distribution consultant in connection with one of the Fair Funds created as a result of the SEC’s investigations of the fund industry that came in the wake of Spitzer’s announcement. See Order Approving Modified Distribution Plan, Mass. Fin. Servs . Co., S.E.C. 56122 (2007), http://www.sec.gov/litigation/admin/2007/34 -56122.pdf [http://perma.cc/G36G-JK3F].

See, eg. , Complaint at ¶¶ 9, 20, New York v. Canary Capital Partners, LLC, No. 2003-402830, 2003 WL 25691660 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. Sept. 3, 2003), http://www.ag.ny.gov/sites /default/files/press-releases/archived/canary_complaint.pdf [http://perma.cc/9GLR-VXG8] (alleging that Bank of America agreed to let a hedge fund place illegal late trades in return for keeping investments in funds sponsored by Bank of America). For a good analysis of the market reaction to the revelation of the scandals, see Stephen Choi & Marcel Kahan , The Market Penalty for Mutual Fund Scandals , 87 B.U. L. Rev. 1021 (2007).

Various sections of the ICA govern conflict of interest transactions See, e.g. , Investment Company Act of 1940, Pub. L. No. 76-768, § 17, 54 Stat. 815 (codified as amended at 15 U.S.C. § 80a-17 (2012)) (banning purchases, sales, borrowing, and loans to or from a fund by “any affiliated person”). The exemptions adopted by the SEC under the ICA are numerous and collected at Investment Company Governance, 69 Fed. Reg. 46,378, 46,379 n.9 (Aug. 2, 2004) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 270).

Investment Company Governance, 69 Fed Reg. at 46,582-82. The SEC also added requirements for fund boards to perform self-assessments at least annually, hold executive sessions for independent directors at least quarterly, and give independent directors authority to hire their own staff. Id . at 46,381. None of these requirements were the focus of subsequent litigation, although each plausibly contributes to both the overall benefits and overall costs of the combined package of conditions, by enhancing the power of independent directors, for both good and ill.

Amy Borrus & Paula Dwyer, Who’s Right, the SEC or Ned Johnson ? , Bloomberg Businessweek , June 27, 2004, http://wwwbusinessweek.com/stories/2004-06-27/whos-right -the-sec-or-ned-johnson [http://perma.cc/9YVJ-76ED].

See Letter from Eric D Router, Senior Vice President and Gen. Counsel, Fidelity Mgmt. & Research Co. to Jonathan G. Katz, Sec’y , U.S. Sec. & Exch. Comm’n (Mar. 18, 2004), http://www.sec.gov/rules/proposed/s70304/fidelity031804.htm [http://perma.cc/UF86-8JGK].

Investment Company Governance, 69 Fed Reg. at 46,386-87 (applying cost-benefit analysis); id. at 46,381-86 (discussing conditions, including qualitative assessment of benefits).

Id at 46,386.

Id at 46,380.

The SEC noted that “[ e] ven accepted at face value, Fidelity’s data constitute muddy and unpersuasive evidence for continuing to allow senior management company officials to sit in the fund chairman’s chair” Id. at 46,383 n.52 (citing John C. Bogle , Founder and Former CEO, Vanguard Group, Remarks Before the Institutional Investor Magazine Mutual Fund Regulation and Compliance Conference (May 5, 2004)).

As noted by Sherwin, this rider was first introduced in S 2908, 108th Cong. (2004), by Senator Gregg on September 15, 2004, and was later incorporated into H.R. 4818, 108th Cong. (2004), the version of the spending bill passed into law, during the House-Senate conference. Sherwin, supra note 15 , at 27 n.159. For Fidelity’s role, see Carrie Johnson, Trade Groups, Firms Push to Ease Tough Federal Scrutiny , Wash. Post , Jan. 3, 2005, http://www.washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A43168-2005Jan2.html [ http://perma.cc/76AJ-K8CB ].

Chamber of Commerce v SEC, 443 F.3d 890 (D.C. Cir. 2006).

The SEC’s Chief Economist was Chester S Spatt , who had been a Professor of Finance at Carnegie-Mellon.

See OEA Memorandum re: Literature Review on Indep Mutual Funds and Dir. from Chester Spatt , Chief Economist, Sec. & Exch. Comm’n , to the Inv. Co. File S7-03-04 (Dec. 29, 2006), http://www.sec.gov/rules/proposed/s70304/oeamemo122906-litreview.pdf [http://perma.cc/XF8H-FXYE]; OEA Memorandum re: Power Study as Related to Indep . Mut . Fund Chairs from Chester S. Spatt , Chief Economist, Sec. & Exch. Comm’n , to the Inv. Co. Governance File S7-03-04 (Dec. 29, 2006), http://www.sec.gov/rules/proposed/s70304/oeamemo122906-powerstudy.pdf [http://perma.cc/4PXD-F42K].

OEA Memorandum re: Literature Review on Indep Mutual Funds and Dir., supra note 249 , at 1. While the Chief Economist did not spell out the point, “structural model” here presumably refers to a model in which potential causal relationships among exogenous and endogenous variables needed to measure fund value or fund performance are specified—in other words, a theoretical model of fund value or performance. See, e.g. , Peter C. Reiss & Frank A. Wolak , Structural Econometric Modeling: Rationales and Examples from Industrial Organization , in 6A Handbook of Econometrics 4277, 4363 (James J. Heckman & Edward E. Leamer eds ., 2007) (contrasting structural models with non-structural “descriptive” empirical models). Most empirical corporate governance research, including research relevant to mutual funds, remains closer to the “descriptive” than to the “structural.”

OEA Memorandum re: Literature Review on Indep Mutual Funds and Dir., supra note 249 , at 2.

Eg. , Sanjai Bhagat & Bernard Black, The Non-Correlation Between Board Independence and Long-Term Firm Performance , 27 J. Corp. L. 231 (2002); Benjamin E. Hermalin & Michael S. Weisbach , The Effects of Board Composition and Direct Incentives on Firm Performance , 20 Fin. Mgmt . 101 (1991); Eugene Kang & Asghar Zardkoohi , Board Leadership Structure and Firm Performance , 13 Corp. Gov.: Int’l Rev . 785 (2005); April Klein, Firm Performance and Board Committee Structure , 41 J.L. & Econ. 275 (1998); Hamid Mehran , Executive Compensation Structure, Ownership, and Firm Performance , 38 J. Fin . Econ . 163 (1995); M. Babajide Wintoki et al., Endogeneity and the Dynamics of Internal Corporate Governance , 105 J. Fin. Econ . 581 (2012).

Eg. , Sanjai Bhagat & Richard H. Jefferis , Jr., The Econometrics of Corporate Governance Studies (2002); Michael R. Roberts & Toni M. Whited, Endogeneity in Empirical Corporate Finance , in 2 Handbook of the Economics of Finance 493 (George M. Constantinides et al. eds ., 2013); Yair Listokin , Interpreting Empirical Estimates of the Effect of Corporate Governance , 10 Am. L. & Econ. Rev. 90 (2008). This does not mean empirical studies of governance are useless. Such studies are essential sources of descriptive information about important organizations, without which neither social scientists nor practitioners can hope to understand them at all. For example, the fact of the extent and generality of variation in governance’s fine details emerged only from such studies. Such studies can provide partial, weak, and provisional evidence about the effects of governance arrangements, and when replicated with sufficient frequency in a variety of settings by a variety of researchers, they may allow tentative inferences to augment raw experience-based judgment in tentative evaluations. They can reject certain theories about governance, prompt refinements in theory, and provide a basis for more serious experimentation. At least over short time frames, they can allow for useful out-of-sample predictions even without reliable proof of causal mechanisms.

Compare, for example, the effect of financial collapse (as in 2008), accounting scandals (as in 2002), a market crash (as in 1987 and 1989), or war (shooting or trade), pandemic, or drought

Thus, as with SOX, a valid criticism of the SEC’s CBA/FR is that the SEC failed to adequately explain why quantitative analysis was not feasible, and that it failed to present an adequate conceptual CBA/FR—not, as argued by others, that it failed to conduct adequate quantitative analysis See , e.g. , Chamber of Commerce v. SEC, 412 F.3d 133, 144 (D.C. Cir. 2005); CCMR Report , supra note 4 , at 9; Edward Sherwin, The Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: What the SEC Ignores in the Rulemaking Process, Why It Matters, and What To Do About It 53, 65 (Working Paper, 2005), http://www.law.harvard.edu/faculty/hjackson/pdfs/CBA.article.doc.pdf [http://perma.cc/7TWL-8GNR]. For example, the SEC never noted in its rule release that heightened independence requirements could result in less informed and more cumbersome boards or divisiveness and conflict on boards, undermine board culture, and dilute the effectiveness of board decision making. Investment Company Governance, 69 Fed. Reg. at 46,386-87. These costs seem likely to swamp the short-term compliance costs on which the SEC, the D.C. Circuit, and commentators have focused. See Letter from John C. Coates IV, Professor of Law and Econ ., to Nancy M. Morris, Sec’y , Sec. & Exch. Comm’n (Mar. 1, 2007), http://www.sec.gov/rules/proposed/s70304/s70304-554.pdf [http://perma.cc/8R5X-F38D] (discussing the costs of an independent board chair).

Chamber of Commerce v SEC, 443 F.3d 890 (D.C. Cir. 2006) (nowhere discussing these costs); Chamber of Commerce v. SEC, 412 F.3d 133 (D.C. Cir. 2005) (same); CCMR Report , supra note 4 , at 4; CCMC Report, supra note 6 , at 29-30; Sherwin, supra note 15 , at 32-33.

See Letter from John C Coates IV , supra note 255 .

I also argued that “[ i ]f [CBA/FR] is to assist the regulatory process, the minimum one would expect before adding regulations is at least some economic evidence that the regulations will provide some benefit” Id. at 2 . I continue to hold that view. But a desire for “evidence” is not the same as a mandate to conduct quantified CBA/FR. One can believe financial regulations aimed at improving or constraining governance are not susceptible to quantified CBA/FR without giving up on the goal of obtaining “evidence” that can inform consideration of the rules and their alternatives. Evidence is commonly adduced in court and in other contexts that do not admit of quantification, reliable causal inference, or anything approaching “science.”

Cf Robert A. Kagan , Adversarial Legalism and American Government , in The New Politics of Public Policy 88 (Marc K. Landy & Martin A. Levin eds ., 1995) (litigation drains agency resources, causing agencies to alter their behavior in an effort to avoid it).

Letter from Warren Buffett, Chairman, Berkshire Hathaway Inc, to Shareholders (Feb. 28, 2002), http://www.berkshirehathaway.com/2001ar/2001letter.html [http://perma.cc/S7WA-BH85].

See Capital Purchase Program: Program Purpose and Overview , US. Dep’t of Treasury (Jan. 15, 2014, 3:10 PM), http://www.treasury.gov/initiatives/financial-stability/TARP-Programs/bank-investment-programs/cap/pages/default.aspx [http://perma.cc/YY5Y-M5RN].

Wells Fargo’s then-CEO has criticized what he viewed as US. government efforts to pressure his company to accept a bailout under the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act (also known as the Troubled Asset Relief Program), and Wells Fargo repaid the investment as soon as it was permitted under the terms of the investment. Mark Calvey , Former Wells Fargo CEO Dick Kovacevich Blasts TARP: An ‘ Unmitigated Disaster , ’ S.F. Bus. Times , June 13, 2012, http://www.bizjournals.com/sanfrancisco/blog/2012/06/wells-fargo-dick-kovacevich-occupy-tarp.html [http://perma.cc/86D4-5NW4]; Wells’ TARP Plan Brings End to Bailout Era , N.Y. Times: DealBook (Dec. 14, 2009, 6:33 PM), http://dealbook.nytimes.com/2009/12/14/wells-fargo-to-repay-25-billion-to-us [http://perma.cc/ZMA2-N7VD]. However, Wells Fargo was found to need more capital in the course of the “stress tests” conducted during the crisis, in circumstances in which not all banks were required to raise capital. Wells Fargo & Co., Annual Report (Form 10-K) 8 (Feb. 26, 2010), http://www.sec.gov/Archives/edgar/data/72971/000095012310017877/f54129e10vk.htm [http://perma.cc/YW49-8TJE] (“[ I]n 2009, the [Federal Reserve] conducted a test under the [Supervisory Capital Assessment Program, i.e., the stress test program] to forecast capital levels . . . in an adverse economic scenario. Following . . . that stress test, the [Federal Reserve] required [Wells Fargo] to generate a $13.7 billion regulatory capital buffer . . . . [Wells Fargo] exceeded this requirement through an $8.6 billion . . . common stock offering . . . . ”).

See Brett W Fawley & Christopher J. Neely, Four Stories of Quantitative Easing , 95 Fed. Reserve Bank St. Louis Rev . 51 (2013), http://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/review/13/01 /Fawley.pdf [http://perma.cc/EV39-BRNT].

See Jennifer G Hill, Why Did Australia Fare So Well in the Global Financial Crisis ? , in The Regulatory Aftermath of the Global Financial Crisis 203, 287 ( Eilís Ferran et al. eds., 2012) (reporting that no bailouts occurred in Australia or Canada, and noting that “[b] etween 2003 and 2005, [Australia’s financial services regulator] created a new regulatory framework, which was focused on close supervision, effective risk management, governance, and strong, well-enforced, capital adequacy rules”); Michael D. Bordo et al., Why Didn’t Canada Have A Banking Crisis in 2008 (or in 1930, or 1907, or . . . )? 25 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 17312, 2011), http://www.nber.org/papers/w17312.pdf [http://perma.cc/ZYUs-CMTD] (“Canadian regulation under OSFI proved tougher than in the United States, mandating higher capital requirements, lower leverage, less securitization, the curtailment of off balance sheet vehicles, and restricting the assets that banks could purchase.”).

See Andrea Beltratti & René M Stulz , The Credit Crisis Around the Globe: Why Did Some Banks Perform Better ? , 105 J. Fin. Econ . 1, 8-10 (2012).

See Basel Committee on Banking Supervision , Bank for Int’l Settlements , http://wwwbis.org/bcbs [http://perma.cc/7YUX-FQPA].

The Federal Reserve supervises systemically important financial institutions and other bank and financial holding companies, as well as state banks that are members of the Federal Reserve System (FRS) The OCC supervises national banks and federal thrifts. The FDIC supervises state FDIC-insured banks that are not members of the FRS and has back-up authority over other insured banks. See Edward V. Murphy, Cong. Research Serv., R43087, Who Regulates Whom and How? An Overview of U.S. Financial Regulatory Policy for Banking and Securities Markets 13, 16 (2013).

See Basel Committee Membership , Bank for Int’l Settlements , http://wwwbis.org/bcbs/membership.htm [http://perma.cc/69B3-76LZ].

Basel Comm on Banking Supervision, Basel III: A Global Regulatory Framework for More Resilient Banks and Banking Systems , Bank for Int’l Settlements 1 (June 2011), http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs189.pdf [http://perma.cc/7D9U-YM8F].

See Basel Comm on Banking Supervision, Basel III: The Liquidity Coverage Ratio and Liquidity Risk Monitoring Tools , Bank for Int’l Settlements paras . 1-3 , at 1 (Jan. 2013), http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs238.pdf [http://perma.cc/DU8G-YDLM]. The new requirements include a liquidity coverage ratio, which requires banks to have enough high quality liquid resources to survive an acute stress scenario lasting for one month, and a net stable funding ratio, designed to address liquidity risk by creating incentives for banks to rely on funding with maturities of a year or longer. Id . paras . 14-17, at 4. In general terms, liquidity is the amount of cash or other assets readily convertible to cash on a timely basis, to meet withdrawal demands or other cash requirements. The Basel Committee also circulated an earlier discussion paper related to liquidity. See Basel Comm. on Banking Supervision, Basel III: International Framework for Liquidity Risk Measurement, Standards and Monitoring , Bank for Int’l Settlements (Dec. 2010), http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs188.pdf [http://perma.cc/6J2Y-64BE].

Under prior capital rules, securitized assets with high credit ratings were given a low risk weighting and so required less capital than other kinds of assets See Basel Comm. on Banking Supervision, Revisions to the Basel Securitisation Framework , Bank for Int’l Settlements 4 (Dec. 2012), http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs236.pdf [http://perma.cc/QF6Z-RBCL] (“The recent financial crisis revealed that external credit ratings often did not adequately reflect the risk of certain structured finance asset classes, such as mortgage backed securities, including but not limited to resecuritisation exposures.”).

See Basel Comm on Banking Supervision, Basel III Counterparty Credit Risk and Exposures to Central Counterparties - Frequently Asked Questions , Bank for Int’l Settlements (Dec. 2012), http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs237.pdf [http://perma.cc/9329-V35D]; Basel Comm. on Banking Supervision, Basel Committee on Banking Supervision Reforms - Basel III , Bank for Int’l Settlements , http://www.bis.org/bcbs/basel3/b3summarytable.pdf [http://perma.cc/D6KL-V4A7]; Basel Comm. on Banking Supervision, Global Systemically Important Banks: Assessment Methodology and the Additional Loss Absorbency Requirement , Bank for Int’l Settlements (July 2011), http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs201.pdf [http://perma.cc/TQH2-UCXP].

See Regulatory Capital Rules: Regulatory Capital, Implementation of Basel III, Capital Adequacy, Transition Provisions, Prompt Corrective Action, Standardized Approach for Risk-Weighted Assets, Market Discipline and Disclosure Requirements, Advanced Approaches Risk-Based Capital Rule, and Market Risk Capital Rule, 78 Fed Reg. 62,018, 62,023 (Oct. 11, 2013) (to be codified at 12 C.F.R. pts. 208, 217, 225) (final rule, consolidating three proposed rules, and noting that there were over 2,500 comments for these proposed rules); Liquidity Coverage Ratio: Liquidity Risk Measurement, Standards and Monitoring, 78 Fed. Reg. 71,818 (proposed Nov. 29, 2013) (to be codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 249); Regulatory Capital Rules: Advanced Approaches Risk-Based Capital Rule; Market Risk Capital Rule, 77 Fed. Reg. 52,978 (proposed Aug. 30, 2012) (to be codified at 12 C.F.R. pts. 3, 217, 324); Regulatory Capital Rules: Regulatory Capital, Implementation of Basel III, Minimum Regulatory Capital Ratios, Capital Adequacy, Transition Provisions, and Prompt Corrective Action, 77 Fed. Reg. 52,792 (proposed Aug. 30, 2012) (to be codified at 12 C.F.R. pts. 208, 217, 225); Regulatory Capital Rules: Standardized Approach for Risk-Weighted Assets; Market Discipline and Disclosure Requirements, 77 Fed. Reg. 52,888 (proposed Aug. 30, 2012) (to be codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 217).

Regulatory Capital Rules: Regulatory Capital, Implementation of Basel III, Capital Adequacy, Transition Provisions, Prompt Corrective Action, Standardized Approach for Risk-Weighted Assets, Market Discipline and Disclosure Requirements, Advanced Approaches Risk-Based Capital Rule, and Market Risk Capital Rule, 78 Fed Reg. at 62,024.

See Basel Comm on Banking Supervision, An Assessment of the Long-Term Economic Impact of Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements , Bank for Int’l Settlements ( Aug. 2010) [hereinafter BCBS 173], http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs173.pdf [http://perma.cc/JL5H-4PU6] (estimating both costs and benefits of higher capital requirements); Macroeconomic Assessment Grp ., Final Report: Assessing the Macroeconomic Impact of the Transition to Stronger Capital and Liquidity Requirements , Bank for Int’l Settlements ( Dec. 2010), http://www.bis.org/publ/othp12.pdf [http://perma.cc/FZ45-39XB] (estimating the effects of higher capital requirements).

Basel Comm on Banking Supervision, Results of the Comprehensive Quantitative Impact Study , Bank for Int’l Settlements 1, 4 ( Dec. 2010), http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs186.pdf [http://perma.cc/BY4F-QSE8]. The Basel Committee compiled those inputs and analyzed the results in a “quantitative impact study,” id . , and the results are reflected in the Committee’s final CBA/FR, Macroeconomic Assessment Grp ., supra note 275 . This consultation was confidential, at both agency and bank levels, and individual bank or national regulator inputs to the Basel Committee process are not available to the public. Id.

The FSA was required to conduct CBA/FR See supra text accompanying note 81 .

Ray Barrell et al, Optimal Regulation of Bank Capital and Liquidity: How To Calibrate New International Standards , Fin. Services Authority (Occasional Paper Series No. 38, July 2009) [hereinafter FSA 38], [http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/occpapers/op38.pdf [http://perma.cc/G7JM-2ZTH]; Sebastian de-Ramon et al., Measuring the Impact of Prudential Policy on the Macroeconomy : A Practical Application to Basel III and Other Responses to the Financial Crisis , Fin. Servs . Auth. (Occasional Paper Series No. 42, May 2012) [hereinafter FSA 42], http://www.fsa.gov.uk/pubs/occpapers/op42.pdf [ http://perma.cc/5TWP-WT65 ].

Eric Posner & E Glen Weyl , Benefit-Cost Analysis for Financial Regulation , 103 Am . Econ. Rev. , May 2013, at 393, 394 (citing Carmen M. Reinhart & Kenneth S. Rogoff , This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly (2009)).

Andrew G Haldane, Exec. Dir., Fin. Stability, Bank of Eng., Address at the Institute of Regulation & Risk in Hong Kong: The $100 Billion Question (Mar. 30, 2010), http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/archive/Documents/historicpubs/speeches/2010/speech433.pdf [http://perma.cc/9SEQ-9KYK]; FSA 42, supra note 280, at 63 tbl.7; Meilan Yan et al., A Cost-Benefit Analysis of Basel III: Some Evidence from the UK 26 tbl.10 (Working Paper, Aug. 20, 2011), http://ssrn.com/abstract=1913433 [http://perma.cc/UAD5-64BB].

This date is from Reinhart & Rogoff , supra note 279 , at 230 fig14.4. Posner and Weyl do not provide details on which of Reinhart and Rogoff’s estimates they used; in some of the latter’s datasets, for example, id . at 295 app.A.1, they list datasets on crises dating back to 1800 or even 1258. I assume few would use data from the thirteenth century in modern CBA/FR.

See infra Part IVA.1.

That a crisis could have zero social cost disconcerted the authors of BCBS 173, supra note 275 , who found the result driven by “definitions of what constitutes a systemic banking crisis For example, some studies assume that Canada had a banking crisis in 1983. While two small banks failed, experts at the Bank of Canada do not consider this event a systemic banking crisis. Unsurprisingly, most studies find zero output costs for this crisis.” Id. at 36 (citation omitted).

John H Boyd et al., The Real Output Losses Associated with Modern Banking Crises , 37 J. Money, Credit & Banking 977, 978, 994 tbl.7 (2005).

BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 34

Id at 35 & tbl.A1.1.

One prominent study asserts that the definitions used in it and in other cross-country studies are “qualitative” Glenn Hoggarth et al ., Costs of Banking System Instability: Some Empirical Evidence , 26 J. Banking & Fin. 825, 829 (2002).

See, eg. , Michael Bordo et al., Is the Crisis Problem Growing More Severe ? , 16 Econ. Pol’y 53, 55 (2001).

See, eg. , Reinhart & Rogoff , supra note 279 , at 8-11 ; FSA 38, supra note 278 , at 12.

See, eg. , Reinhart & Rogoff , supra note 279 , at 8-11; Bordo et al., supra note 290 , at 55; FSA 38, supra note 278 , at 12.

See, eg. , Bordo et al., supra note 290 , at 55 ; FSA 38, supra note 278 , at 12.

See, eg. , Boyd et al., supra note 284 , at 980-81.

See, eg. , FSA 38, supra note 278 , at 12.

See, eg. , Bordo et al., supra note 290 , at 55.

As the FSA noted, the use of binary crisis dummies (as is typical in the studies reviewed here) “inevitably mean[s] that the start and end dates are ambiguous” FSA 38, supra note 278 , at 12. The use of annual dummies allows for up to twenty-two months of variance in actual duration without affecting the data used (eleven months for the start date, eleven months for the end date), and, “[ s] ince the end-dates are to some extent subjectively chosen[,] there are potential endogeneity problems with estimation: the explanatory variables will be affected by ongoing crises.” Id.

Eg. , Bordo et al., supra note 290 , at 68 tbl.3.

Boyd et al, supra note 284 , at 980 (comparing their choice of twenty-three crises with 160 “or so” identified by Gerard Caprio , Jr. & Daniela Klingebiel , Bank Insolvency: Bad Luck, Bad Policy, or Bad Banking ? , in Annual World Bank Conference on Development Economics (Michael Bruno & Boris Pleskovic eds., 1997)); see also BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 9 (“Different authors classify crises differently. Reinhart and Rogoff (2008) find 34 crises over the 25 year period, while Laeven and Valencia (2008) report only 24.”).

If a stable or smooth relationship existed between the number of crises and the average losses caused by crises, then choices affecting size might be balanced by effects in the second component of the CBA/FR of capital rules, namely, the probability of a crisis, but no such relationship is evident from the studies

R&R concede the spreadsheet error, see Full Response from Reinhart and Rogoff , NY. Times: Economix , Apr. 17, 2013, http://www.nytimes.com/interactive/2013/04/17/business/17economix-response.html [http://perma.cc/W5VJ-2GFA], but not other critiques of their estimates, see id . ; Paul Krugman , Reinhart- Rogoff Continued , N.Y. Times: Conscience of a Liberal (Apr. 16, 2013, 7:31 PM), http://www.krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/04/16/reinhart-rogoff-continued [http://perma.cc/S6AW-476F]. Krugman takes R&R to task for their response to their critics; R&R take Krugman to task for his taking them to task. Carmen M. Reinhart, Letter to PK , Carmen M. Reinhart Author Website (May 25, 2013), http://www.carmenreinhart.com/letter-to-pk [http://perma.cc/BLQ3-BM75].

The original R&R publication was a working paper released in early 2010 See Carmen M. Reinhart & Kenneth S. Rogoff , Growth in a Time of Debt (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 15639, 2010), http://www.nber.org/papers/w15639.pdf [http://perma.cc/9QR3-2NGL]. The data flaw did not get noticed until 2013. See Thomas Herndon et al., Does High Public Debt Consistently Stifle Economic Growth? A Critique of Reinhart and Rogoff (Political Econ. Research Inst., Working Paper No. 322, 2013), http://www.peri.umass.edu/236/hash/31e2ff374b6377b2ddec04deaa6388b1/publication/566 [http://perma.cc/W3TL-NX6B].

As noted in Herndon et al, supra note 302 , at 4, R&R’s 2010 paper “is the only evidence cited in the ‘Paul Ryan Budget’ on the consequences of high public debt for economic growth.” British politician George Osborne (later Chancellor of the Exchequer) relied on R&R to argue most financial crises are caused by excessive public debt in a speech quoted in an April 2013 New Yorker article on the R&R kerfuffle. John Cassidy, The Reinhart and Rogoff Controversy: A Summing Up , New Yorker: John Cassidy, Apr. 26, 2013, http://www.newyorker.com/rational-irrationality/the-rogoff-and-reinhart-controversy-a-summing-up .html [http://perma.cc/K33X-YCR5].

Herndon et al, supra note 302 , at 5.

Carmen M Reinhart & Kenneth S. Rogoff , Op-Ed, Reinhart and Rogoff : Responding to Our Critics , N.Y. Times, Apr. 25, 2013, http://www.nytimes.com/2013/04/26/opinion/reinhart-and-rogoff-responding-to-our-critics.html [http://perma.cc/46UB-RH8V].

BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 3 (“Using the median estimate . . across all comparable studies . . . each 1 percentage point reduction in the annual probability of a crisis yields an expected benefit per year equal to 0.6% of output when banking crises are allowed to have a permanent effect on real activity. Using the median estimate . . . when crises are seen to have only a temporary effect . . . each 1 percentage point reduction . . . yields an expected benefit per year equal to 0.2% of output.”).

BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 29 tbl8 (subtracting amounts in the column labeled “Net benefits (large permanent effect)” from amounts in the column labeled “Net benefits (no permanent effect),” adding back the amount in column labeled “Expected costs,” and comparing the difference).

BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 36 (noting that “median losses are sensitive to the choice of discount rate,” and that “the median loss . . is 82% if a discount rate of 2.5% is used” but is 63% if 5% is assumed). On discount rates in CBA/FR, see generally Pindyck , supra note 224 .

See generally Tetlock , supra note 64

Edward Ashbee , Fiscal Policy Responses to the Economic Crisis in the United Kingdom and the United States: A Comparative Assessment 1 (Am Political Sci. Ass’n , Annual Meeting Paper, 2011), http://ssrn.com/abstract=1899700 [http://perma.cc/Y8BN-8RNV].

See Michael Joyce, Quantitative Easing and Other Unconventional Monetary Policies: Bank of England Conference Summary , 52 Bank Eng Q. Bull. 48, 49 (2012), http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/quarterlybulletin/qb1201.pdf [http://perma.cc/NU62-CQ3V] (contrasting the U.S., U.K., and European Central Bank responses to the crisis); Leonardo Gambacorta et al., The Effectiveness of Unconventional Monetary Policy at the Zero Lower Bound: A Cross-Country Analysis 5-6 (Bank for Int’l Settlements, Working Paper No. 384, 2012), http://www.bis.org/publ/work384.pdf [http://perma.cc/FU6G-LEVM].

Eg. , James R. Lothian, U.S. Monetary Policy and the Financial Crisis , 6 J. Econ. Asymmetries 25, 27-28 (2009).

Eg. , Mariko Fujii & Masahiro Kawai, Lessons from Japan’s Banking Crisis, 1991-2005 , at 4-8 (Asian Dev. Bank Inst., Working Paper No. 222, 2010), http://www.adbi.org/files/2010.06.29.wp222.lessons.japan.banking.crisis.1991.2005.pdf [http://perma.cc/RT9B-S2UM].

Eg. , Lothian, supra note 312 ; Adam S. Posen, External Member of the Monetary Policy Comm., Bank of Eng. and Senior Fellow, Peterson Inst. for Int’l Econ ., Why Is Their Recovery Better Than Ours? (Even Though Neither Is Good Enough), Speech at the National Institute of Economic and Social Research, London 2 (Mar. 27, 2012), http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/Documents/speeches/2012/speech560.pdf [http://perma.cc/WK2L-U3LE] (“[ T]he US has had significantly more GDP growth with somewhat lower inflation over the last thirty-two months than in the UK . . . [because, among other factors] there was significantly less net withdrawal of fiscal stimulus in the US than the UK.”); Jeremy C. Stein, Member, Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve, Evaluating Large-Scale Asset Purchases , Remarks at the Brookings Institution (Oct. 11, 2012), http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/stein20121011a.htm [http://perma.cc/P8FH-K6W4] (noting that large-scale asset purchases by the Federal Reserve “played a significant role in supporting economic activity and in preventing a worrisome undershoot of the Committee’s inflation objective”); Martin Feldstein, Quantitative Easing and America’s Economic Rebound , Project Syndicate (Feb. 24, 2011), http://www.project-syndicate.org/commentary/quantitative-easing-and-america-s-economic-rebound [http://perma.cc/N8WQ-JJ8S] (suggesting that the 2011 economic rebound in the United States was due to increases in stock prices and consumer spending driven by quantitative easing, which would not be sustainable beyond 2011).

It is tempting to suggest that CBA/FR could be made tractable by just ignoring future policy responses in modeling the costs of future crises But that is to make an implicit assumption, too, and one that is more likely to be counterfactual than an assumption based on past (or at least recent) policy responses. The assumption would tend to inflate the cost of future crises beyond reasonable levels because every crisis would tend, absent a policy response, to generate large and sustained reductions in GDP, as in the Great Depression. The result would be to expand greatly the range of defensible regulations and to eliminate any disciplining effect of CBA/FR while adding a great deal of camouflage to the regulatory process.

BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 9 (citing Carmen M Reinhart & Kenneth S. Rogoff , Banking Crises: An Equal Opportunity Menace (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 14587, 2008), http://www.nber.org/papers/w14587 [http://perma.cc/BX8V-CD5F]); Luc Laeven & Fabian Valencia, Systemic Banking Crises: A New Database (Int’l Monetary Fund, Working Paper No. 08-224, 2008, https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2008/wp08224.pdf [http://perma.cc/FVC8-7XHY].

See BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 39 tblA1.4.

FSA 38, supra note 278 , at 12

BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 9

FSA 38, supra note 278 , at 15 tbl2.

FSA 42, supra note 278 , at 38 & tbl5.1, adds current account balances to the logit model used in FSA 38, and adjusts the data for comparability across countries. The modest change “results in a significant improvement in” the model’s classification performance. Id . FSA 42 also examines a larger family of different crisis prediction models. Id . at 38-45. The authors later present information on the overall uncertainty associated with their bottom-line estimates of the net benefits of higher capital requirements, id. at 60-64, but they do not break out the specific potential impact of different models of crisis frequency.

A fourth, equally difficult challenge is to anticipate and model the private market responses to the rule, particularly responses that include moving assets or activities outside of regulated banks into unregulated entities—that is, Basel III may shift risk into “shadow banks” If those assets or activities nevertheless create risks for the financial system as a whole, or otherwise generate external risks, such a response would represent an offset to the benefits of higher capital requirements, to be included on the cost side of the CBA/FR ledger.

FSA 42, supra note 278 , at 47

The Financial Crisis Response in Charts , US. Dep’t Treasury 12 (Apr. 2012), http://www.treasury.gov/resource-center/data-chart-center/Documents/20120413_FinancialCrisisResponse.pdf [http://perma.cc/5HUD-ZBGN].

Id at 50-51.

BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 21-22; FSA 38, supra note 278 , at 39 & tbl4.

BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 22, notes that reducing the assumed cost of bank equity from the 1993 to 2007 average of 148% to 10.0% cuts the impact of higher capital requirements from a one-to-thirteen basis point impact to a one-to-seven basis point impact. The report goes on to note that “there are good reasons to believe that the cost of capital would decline in response to a reduction in bank leverage” due to increased bank capital requirements, and that “in the limit, the change in the cost of capital could reduce to tax effects.” Id. (citing Franco Modigliani & Merton H. Miller, The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment , 48 Am. Econ. Rev. 261 (1958) (finding that, under stylized assumptions, a firm’s returns are invariant to how it finances itself, but for taxes)). As BCBS 173 notes, prior research suggests that the long-run effect on banks’ funding costs of higher capital requirements is likely to be smaller than the numbers used in BCBS 173—a four percentage point increase is assumed to increase borrowing costs by fifty-two basis points in BCBS 173, supra note 277, at 23 tbl.6, versus only twenty basis points in Douglas J. Elliott, A Further Exploration of Bank Capital Requirements: Effects of Competition from Other Financial Sectors and Effects of Size of Bank or Borrower and of Loan Type , Brookings Inst. 22 (Jan. 28, 2010), http://www.brookings.edu/~/media/research/files/papers/2010/1/29%20capital%20elliott/0129_capital_requirements_elliott.pdf [http://perma.cc/9C6R-5GPF], and ten to eighteen basis points in Anil K. Kashyap et al., An Analysis of the Impact of “Substantially Heightened” Capital Requirements on Large Financial Institutions 17 (May 2010) (unpublished manuscript), http://faculty.chicagobooth.edu/anil.kashyap/research/papers/an_analysis_of_the_impact_of_substantially_heightened-Capital-Requirements-on-Financial-Institutions.pdf [http://perma.cc/WY6E-GHRE]. For a discussion of some of the drivers of disagreements on the effect of capital requirements on lending costs, see Douglas J. Elliott, Higher Bank Capital Requirements Would Come at a Price , Brookings Inst. (Feb. 20, 2013) http://www.brookings.edu/research/papers/2013/02/20-bank-capital-requirements-elliott [http://perma.cc/GJ7J-LRDL].

Anat R Admati et al., Fallacies, Irrelevant Facts, and Myths in the Discussion of Capital Regulation: Why Bank Equity Is Not Socially Expensive , at i (Stanford Graduate Sch. of Bus. Working Paper No. 2065, 2013), http://www.gsb.stanford.edu/sites/default/files/research/documents/Fallacies%20Nov%201.pdf [http://perma.cc/4LR5-97HX]. These authors also rely on Modigliani & Miller , supra note 329 .

Admati et al, supra note 330 , at 19-20.

Id at 21-23.

BCBS 173, supra note 275 , at 27 tbl7.

Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub L. No. 111-203, § 619, 124 Stat. 1376, 1620 (2010) (codified at 12 U.S.C. § 1851 (2012)). Section 619 is called the “Volcker Rule” because former Federal Reserve Board Chairman Paul Volcker was a prominent backer of the law.

The banking agencies and the SEC issued a joint final rule Prohibitions and Restrictions on Proprietary Trading and Certain Interests in, and Relationships with, Hedge Funds and Private Equity Funds, 79 Fed. Reg. 5,536 (Jan. 31, 2014) (to be codified at 12 C.F.R. pt. 44 (OCC); 12 C.F.R. pt. 248 (Fed. Reserve); 12 C.F.R. pt. 351 (FDIC); 17 C.F.R. pt. 255 (SEC)). The CFTC issued a final rule separately. Prohibitions and Restrictions on Proprietary Trading and Certain Interests in, and Relationships with, Hedge Funds and Private Equity Funds, 79 F ed. Reg . 5,808 ( Jan. 31, 2014) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 75).

Bank Holding Company Act of 1956, Pub L. No. 84-511, 70 Stat. 133 (codified as amended in scattered sections of 12 U.S.C.) The Bank Holding Company Act of 1956 (BHCA) initially contained a broad regulatory delegation of authority to the Federal Reserve Board to “issue such regulations and orders as may be necessary to enable it to administer and carry out the purposes” of the Act and to “prevent evasions thereof.” Id. § 5(b), 70 Stat. at 137. That provision remains in 12 U.S.C. § 1844(b), with amendments to clarify that the authority includes the power to adopt capital requirements for bank holding companies.

See 7 US.C. § 19(a)(1) (2012) (requiring the CFTC to “consider the costs and benefits” of its regulatory actions). This is true even though the SEC and the CFTC were also required to adopt the Volcker Rule because their authority (and mandate) to do so is (unusually) in the BHCA, not the statutes that traditionally authorize them to act. Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, Analysis of 12 CFR Part 44 , U.S. Dep’t Treasury (Mar. 2014), http://www.occ.gov/topics/laws-regulations/legislation-of-interest/volcker-analysis.pdf [http://perma.cc/BA7-R4PG].

The specific section that authorizes the Volcker Rule, 12 US.C. § 1851 (2012), added to the BHCA by the Dodd-Frank Act, contains a similarly broad grant of authority and does not condition rulemaking on any particular finding or process, other than (1) to “consider” a statutorily mandated January 2011 study of how to implement the section conducted by the Financial Stability Oversight Council, see 12 U.S.C. § 1851(b)(1)-(2)(A) (2012); Study & Recommendations on Prohibitions on Proprietary Trading & Certain Relationships with Hedge Funds & Private Equity Funds , Fin. Stability Oversight Council (Jan. 2011), http://www.treasury.gov/initiatives/documents/volcker%20sec%20%20619%20study%20final%201%2018%2011%20rg.pdf [http://perma.cc/JFW4-E2XZ]; and (2) to coordinate rulemaking among the Federal Reserve Board, FDIC, OCC, SEC, and CFTC so as to “ assur [ e], to the extent possible, that such regulations are comparable and provide for consistent application and implementation . . . to avoid providing advantages or imposing disadvantages to the companies affected . . . and to protect the safety and soundness of banking entities and nonbank financial companies supervised” by the Federal Reserve, 12 U.S.C. § 1851(b)(2)(B)(ii) (2012).

Prohibitions and Restrictions on Proprietary Trading, 79 Fed Reg. at 65,744 (conducting analysis under the PRA); id. at 65,778 (conducting analysis under the RFA). The American Bankers Association (ABA) and other plaintiffs sued to enjoin enforcement of the Volcker Rule on the ground that the agencies’ RFA analysis failed to consider the rule’s “significant economic impact on a substantial number of community banks.” See Emergency Motion of Petitioners for Stay of Agency Action Pending Review at 15, Am. Bankers Ass’n v. Bd. of Governors of the Fed. Reserve Sys ., No. 13-1310 (D.C. Cir. Dec. 24, 2013), http://www.aba.com/Issues/Documents/12-24-13ABAEmergencyMotionforStayofVolckerRuleOwnershipInterestProvision.pdf [http://perma.cc/6HSX-PNE8]. The Joint Volcker Rule Release specifically addressed potential impacts by exempting banks below various specified size thresholds from reporting and compliance burdens. The ABA suit focuses on one indirect effect of the rule, which is to ban “banking entities” (including all depository institutions, small or large) from holding “ownership interests” in hedge and private equity funds (Subpart C of the Volcker Rule), including debt instruments that give holders the right to remove a collateral manager for a collateralized debt obligation–an entity that holds multiple trust-preferred or other securities, which (as the ABA in its papers admits) collapsed in value during the financial crisis. See id. at 2, 7.

See Office of the Comptroller of the Currency , supra note 337

Id at 18-22. The FSOC also identified the benefit that the rule would reduce the risk that banks have effective liability for nominally off-balance sheet funds they sponsor. Fin. Stability Oversight Council, supra note 340, at 56.

Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, supra note 337 , at 1

Cf James D. Cox et al., A Better Path Forward on the Volcker Rule and the Lincoln Amendment , Bipartisan Pol’y Center 8 (Oct. 2013), http://www.sec.gov/comments/s7-41-11/s74111-648.pdf [http://perma.cc/4QPL-27Z9].

See Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, supra note 337 , at 1, 23

Shanny Basar , Paul Volcker Fights for Volcker Rule , Fin. News (Feb. 14, 2012), http://www.efinancialnews.com/story/2012-02-14/paul-volcker-on-volcker-rule [http://perma.cc/8R2E-5PZ2]; Bill Moyers, Paul Volcker on the Volcker Rule , Moyers & Co. (Apr. 5, 2012), http://billmoyers.com/segment/paul-volcker-on-the-volcker-rule [ http://perma.cc/5DUN-TWXP ].

Office of the Comptroller of the Currency, supra note 337 , at 17 (citing Joel Hasbrouck, Trading Costs and Returns for US. Equities: Estimating Effective Costs from Daily Data , 64 J. Fin. 1445 (2009)).

Id at 1, 23 .

See CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 13-16

Cross-Border Security-Based Swap Activities, 78 Fed Reg. 30,968 (proposed May 23, 2013) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 240, 242, 249) [hereinafter Cross-Border Swap Release].

The gap was cemented by the Commodity Futures Modernization Act of 2000, Pub L. No. 106-554, 114 Stat. 2763, 2763A-365. The 262-page bill, attached as an appendix to a budget bill, barred the SEC from regulating OTC derivatives as “securities” and the CFTC from regulating them as “futures,” leaving regulation only through general (and much less specific) “safety and soundness” oversight by regulatory supervisors of OTC issuers and users (which was non-existent for companies that did not accept deposits, invest or deal in securities or futures, or underwrite or sell insurance, including companies that were affiliated with regulated entities, such as AIG). See Sheila Bair, Bull by the Horns: Fighting To Save Main Street from Wall Street and Wall Street from Itself 333 (2012); Simon Johnson & James Kwak , 13 Bankers: The Wall Street Takeover and the Next Financial Meltdown 7-11, 78-82, 92, 121-26, 134-37, 169-70, 202 (2010).

See Report Pursuant to Section 129 of the Emergency Economic Stabilization Act of 2008: Restructuring of the Government’s Financial Support to the American International Group, Inc on March 2, 2009 , Fed. Reserve Sys. (2009) , http://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/files/129aigrestructure03022009.pdf [http://perma.cc/V6J8-HNLW].

The CFTC now regulates “swaps,” the SEC now regulates “security-based swaps,” and both have authority over “mixed swaps” Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act, Pub. L. No. 111-203, §§ 721, 761, 124 Stat. 1376, 1658-72, 1754-59 (2010). A “swap” is a contract that requires conditional payments between counterparties derived from changes in specified prices or events, generally related to financial markets, such as interest or currency exchange rates, but can also include “credit” events, such as the default by a borrower on an unrelated “reference” security or loan.

Regulated entities include swap dealers, major swap participants, data repositories, clearing agencies, and execution facilities Id. Where regulated by the SEC, relevant entities have the phrase “security-based” added to qualify “swap,” but otherwise the definitions are identical to those applicable to the CFTC for other swaps. Id. § 761. For definitions of “Swap Dealer,” “Security-Based Swap Dealer,” “Major Swap Participant,” “Major Security-Based Swap Participant” and “Eligible Contract Participant,” see 77 Fed. Reg. 30,596, 30,751-53 (May 23, 2012) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 1, 240).

Further Definition of “Swap,” “Security-Based Swap,” and “Security-Based Swap Agreement”; Mixed Swaps; Security-Based Swap Agreement Recordkeeping, 77 Fed Reg. 48,208 (Aug. 13, 2012) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 1, 230, 240, 241) (adopting product definitions); Further Definition of “Swap Dealer,” 77 Fed. Reg. at 30,596 (adopting intermediary definitions); see also Further Definition of “Swap Dealer,” “Security-Based Swap Dealer,” “Major Swap Participant” and “Eligible Contract Participant,” 75 Fed. Reg. 80,174 (proposed Dec. 21, 2010) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 1, 240) (proposing intermediary definitions).

Capital Margin and Segregation Requirements for Security-Based Swap Dealers and Major Security-Based Swap Participants and Capital Requirements for Broker-Dealers, 77 Fed Reg. 70,214 (Nov. 23, 2012) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) (proposing capital, margin, and segregation rules); Clearing Agency Standards, 77 Fed. Reg. 66,220 (Nov. 2, 2012) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) (adopting clearing agency standards); Process for Submissions for Review of Security-Based Swaps for Mandatory Clearing and Notice Filing Requirements for Clearing Agencies; Technical Amendments to Rule 19b-4 and Form 19b-4 Applicable to All Self-Regulatory Organizations, 77 Fed. Reg. 41,602 (July 13, 2012) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 240, 249) (adopting clearing procedures); Registration of Security-Based Swap Dealers and Major Security-Based Swap Participants, 76 Fed. Reg. 65,784 (Oct. 24, 2011) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 240, 249) (proposing registration rules for dealers and major swap participants); Business Conduct Standards for Security-Based Swap Dealers and Major Security-Based Swap Participants, 76 Fed. Reg. 42,396 (July 18, 2011) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) (proposing standards for external business conduct); Registration and Regulation of Security-Based Swap Execution Facilities, 76 Fed. Reg. 10,948 (Feb. 29, 2011) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 240, 242, 249) (proposing registration framework for execution facilities); Trade Acknowledgment and Verification of Security-Based Swap Transactions, 76 Fed. Reg. 3,859 (Jan. 21, 2011) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) (proposing trade acknowledgement rules); End-User Exception to Mandatory Clearing of Security-Based Swaps, 75 Fed. Reg. 79,992 (Dec. 21, 2010) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) (proposing end-user exceptions); Security-Based Swap Data Repository Registration, Duties, and Core Principles, 75 Fed. Reg. 77,306 (Dec. 10, 2010) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 240, 249), corrected at 75 Fed. Reg. 79,320 (Dec. 20, 2010) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 240, 249) and 76 Fed. Reg. 2,287 (Jan. 13, 2011) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 240, 249) (proposing data repository rules); Regulation SBSR-Reporting and Dissemination of Security-Based Swap Information, 75 Fed. Reg. 75,208 (Dec. 2, 2010) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pts. 240, 242) (proposing reporting rules).

Dodd-Frank Act § 752.

See 77 Fed Reg. 70,214, 70,299-328 (Nov. 23, 2012) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) (showing that economic analysis takes up roughly 20% of the total release); 77 Fed. Reg. 66,220, 66,263-84 (Nov. 2, 2012) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) (showing that economic analysis takes up roughly 30% of the total release); 77 Fed. Reg. 30,596, 30,722-42 (May 23, 2012) (to be codified at 17 C.F.R. pt. 240) (showing that economic analysis takes up roughly 12% of the total release).

See CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 14

Id (emphasis added). The CCMR Report does not provide any specific cites or examples from within the Cross-Border Swap Release to back up this characterization, instead citing to the release as a whole. Id.

Cross-Border Swap Release, supra note 352, at 386

Id at 413-16.

Id at 416-18.

Id at 509-10. In the discussion of the benefits of the rules covering swap executive facilities, there is no quantification, nor does the release quantify major potential non-compliance costs of such rules, which are noted in qualitative terms in the release and include the possibility that disclosure obligations will drive swap participants from the market, reducing liquidity, or force participants to fragment trades to discourage front-running, resulting in greater transaction costs. Id . at 505-08 (benefits), 510-12 (non-quantifiable costs).

See CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 13-16.

Eg. , Cross-Border Swap Release, supra note 352 at 16 n.5, 34 n.76, 356 & n.1218, 359 & n.1226, 364-66, 365 nn.1245-46, 366 n.1251, 371, 373, 388 n.1301, 392-93. All of these estimates relate to the less important assessment costs, the scope of or changes in relevant markets, or other data, and none are estimates of the more important programmatic costs or programmatic benefits.

For example, in assessing how much voluntary swap clearing is already occurring, the release notes that “if the counterparties choose to transact in a reference entity that is accepted for clearing in a currency other than US. dollars, the transaction is no longer eligible for clearing.” Id. at 486 n.1618. This fact would be of significance for assessing the rules, since one would expect many cross-border swaps to be denominated in other currencies. No data on the currency profile of cross-border swaps is provided. As another example, the release states in another footnote the fact that less than five percent of margin received by swaps association members was segregated with a third-party custodian. Id. at 467 n.1549. This fact directly bears on the potential gross benefits of a rule requiring segregation.

Cross-Border Swap Release, supra note 352, at 467-68 (footnotes omitted)

I think thirty-five words could preserve the meaning: “Segregation may protect customers, depending on US. and foreign laws, and if so may increase market confidence and the value of swaps, consistent with our experience with broker-dealer segregation, but those benefits cannot be quantified.”

George Parker & Brooke Masters, Osborne Abolishes FSA and Boosts Bank , Fin Times, June 16, 2010, http://www.ft.com/intl/cms/s/0/0203b99e-797f-11df-b063-00144feabdc0.html [ http://perma.cc/BSR2-7GA5 ]. The theory of the split-up of the FSA was that it had neglected systemic issues due to a “pre-occupation with consumer protection matters.” Eilis Ferran , Regulatory Lessons from the Payment Protection Insurance Mis -selling Scandal in the UK , 13 Eur. Bus. Org. L. Rev . 247, 248 (2012). Going forward, the Prudential Regulation Authority is meant to engage in prudential supervision, while the Financial Conduct Authority will govern consumer finance. Id.

Mortgage Market Review: Proposed Package of Reforms , Consultation Paper CP11/31 , Fin Servs . Auth . 7 (Dec. 2011), https://www.fca.org.uk/static/documents/consultation-papers/fsa-cp11-31.pdf [https://perma.cc/K3YW-VWUN].

See supra note 83

Mortgage Market Review , supra note 375, at A1 :1

Id at A1 :3 . The FSA’s conceptual CBA/FR is much more complex than depicted in the text. In one figure alone, it identifies four channels for reforms to affect welfare by cutting both affordable and unaffordable loans and increasing the suitability of loans made: (1) reducing resources spent on loans in arrears or repossession; (2) changing welfare from fewer loans; (3) changes in the buy-to-let mortgage market; and (4) lower home prices. Id . at A1 :11 . The reforms also affect competition and raise compliance costs, increasing mortgage prices and contributing to lower home prices. Lower home prices would cut the odds of a new crisis, benefiting the economy, and would also affect the economy through the rental, savings, and pension markets. All this would be happening simultaneously with changes in the identified baseline, such as market corrections in the home loan market; stricter prudential requirements, such as those imposed under Basel III; the collapse and re-launch of a new securitization market; and changes in the supply and demand for housing due to government policy changes, partly driven in turn by the macroeconomic loss. The FSA’s efforts to guesstimate the costs and benefits of the reforms aim at a subset of these channels. Other effects (e.g., changes in monetary or fiscal policy, effects on the “buy-to-let” market, effects on competition) are not quantified “because they are unlikely to be significant or because data constraints prevent us from providing any meaningful estimate.” Id . Also not quantified were benefits from reduced transfers of homes from borrowers to mortgagors, because although reducing transfers “is likely to be regarded as socially beneficial . . . it is difficult to assess the size of the benefit relative to the size of the transfer.” Id . at A1 :27 . Nevertheless, despite this complexity, the bottom line of the FSA’s CBA is driven by what is described in the text. Id . at A1 :8 -9 (noting that “[o] verall CBA balance” is dominated by net well-being benefit).

Impairment was defined as either being in arrears (that is, paying late) or having a home repossessed Id . at A1 :27 . The breakdown between these types was roughly 85%/15%. See id.

Id at A1 :32 . For the other two reforms, the FSA used a separate “model” that simply identified a subset of loans that passed the affordability test but were made to borrowers with high debt-service ratios (mortgage payments to after-tax income), which was taken as a proxy for loan non-affordability. Id . at 141.

Id at A1 :4 . This cut-off point was identified by looking visually at a plot of the average underwriting risk scores by the lenders in its sample, identifying a region in which the scores increased at an increasing rate, selecting the midpoint of the visually identified range, and usually the average underwriting score for the lender so identified. Id . at A1 :35 . It then arbitrarily chose a range that bracketed this score by a round +/- 0.1. Id . at A1 :36 .

Id at A1 :4 . The FSA broke its sample into two sub-periods—2005 to 2007 and 2009 to 2010—to “construct different estimates of the impacts the affordability assessment would have in boom and subdued periods” of lending. Id . at A1 :39 . The FSA does note that this period experienced generally low (by historical standards) and falling interest rates, which likely means its estimates of loan defaults are low by historical standards; this may have led it to underestimate the benefits of its rules. Id . at A1 :32 .

Id at A1 :8 . To do this, the FSA estimated the likely impact of the reforms on the size of loans that would be made, breaking down loans into those of new buyers, home movers, and re-mortgagors. Id . at A1 :69 -71. For new buyers, loans were reduced until they “ compli [ ed ]” with the rules under the FSA’s model, unless the reduction exceeded an arbitrarily chosen 30%, at which point the FSA assumed (absent data) the loan would be foregone. Id. at 70-71. For other borrowers, they estimated the impact on the marginal increased loan of the new rules. Id . Of these, the FSA estimated that 75,000 would obtain a smaller mortgage while the rest would be pushed to delay their borrowing. Id . at A1 :79 .

Id at A1 :76 . The FSA partly motivates this strong pair of assumptions by further assuming that “most borrowers would prefer to borrow affordably.” Id .

Id at A1 :26 . “Others whose borrowing is affected by the [rules] would in any case not have experienced mortgage impairment. These consumers experience only a reduction in well-being (a cost), for example from having to buy a less desirable property, from delaying their property purchase or, in the case of some re-mortgagors, from not obtaining desired additional lending to support consumption.” Id . (emphasis added). The FSA implicitly defends this assumption with the claim that “some of these [borrowers] would have been willing and able to deal with high repayment burdens without much stress.” Id . at A1 :78 .

Id at A1 :76 .

Id at A1 :80 .

Id at A1 :82 -84. The FSA refers to them as “weights.” Id . at A1 :83 .

The FSA generated a variety of comparative statics for different subgroups of borrowers and different types of housing-related events Id . at A1 :82 -84. Because of the variety of comparisons possible, there is no single ratio that emerges from the analysis, other than the general qualitative conclusion that effects of payment problems and defaults are “much greater” than the effects of delayed or foregone housing improvements. Id. at A1 :83 .

Id at A1 :84 . Positive effects were larger during housing booms, with slightly negative effects in subdued markets. Id .

Id at A1 :85 -86.

Id at A1 :8 , A1:86.

Id at A1 :8 .

Id at A1 :8 , A1:102-09.

Id at A1 :112 .

The National Institute for Economic and Social Research created the model, and describes it as using “a ‘New-Keynesian’ framework in that agents are presumed to be forward-looking but nominal rigidities slow the process of adjustment to external events” See Model Overview , Nat’l Inst. Global Econ. Model , http://nimodel.niesr.ac.uk/nigem -intro/nigemintro.php?t=2&b=1 [http://perma.cc/8VXH-6QP6].

Mortgage Market Review , supra note 375, at A1 :72 This modeling was off a baseline that took into account the effects of Basel III estimated by the FSA, id . at A1:72 n.37, and so builds in all of the uncertainties and assumptions of that exercise, see infra Part III.C, along with a variety of other assumptions used to calibrate the NiGEM model, including assumptions about economic growth, inflation, and home prices, and how those macroeconomic forces interact. Id. at A1 :72 -74.

These categories were (1) a reduction in home lending due to increased lending costs from the rules, (2) reduced home prices, which lower household expectations of capital gains from investments in homes, (3) increased household savings and reduced consumption to offset the reduction in expected home investments, (4) decreased inflation and lower central and interbank borrowing rates due to reduced consumption, increased savings, and lower household borrowing, (5) increased business lending as banks use funds freed up by reduced household and mortgage borrowing, and because of the lower bank rate, and (6) increased business investment due to additional business lending, which adds to productive capacity and increases overall output Id. at A1 :72 -74.

Id at A1 :74 .

This discount rate is mentioned in passing in another part of the FSA’s CBA/FR, without explanation of how it was derived Id . at A1 :112 . The FSA does not translate its macroeconomic impact estimates into present values.

Id at A1 :9 .

This may suggest that if new CBA/FR mandates are to be adopted, which Part IV below argues against, they should be confined to the consumer protection context

Mortgage Market Review , supra note 375, at A1 :85

Id at A1 :70 n.33. The FSA defends thirty percent as more realistic than zero or 100%, which seems right, but better would have been to present a sensitivity analysis for this assumption.

Id at A1 :79 n.42. As the FSA laconically notes, “it is therefore likely that over the long run we are over-estimating the impacts of the [rules] on lending volumes in the market.” Id.

Id at A1 :83 . This means that benefits are likely understated.

Id at A1 :82 . This assumption seems implausible because borrowers will tend to “stretch” in their borrowing for housing in response to career developments, which will correlate with time, so any time trends in well-being reports will be reflected in the implicit before-and-after comparisons.

Id at A1 :93 . Better would have been to include some data from periods of high or rising interest rates, but the FSA faced data limitations similar to those faced by all financial regulators.

Id. at A1 :87 .

Cf id . at A1:8 n.3, A1:27. The FSA noted this assumption was likely counterfactual, although it did not elaborate on why—presumably because the non-market value of a home to the defaulting borrower exceeds the value of the home to the lender and/or a new buyer, on average.

Compare with OMB Guidance, supra note 20, at 2 (“It is usually necessary to provide a sensitivity analysis to reveal whether, and to what extent, the results of the analysis are sensitive to plausible changes in the main assumptions and numeric inputs”).

Mortgage Market Review , supra note 375, at A1 :40 This estimate is for the affordability component of the reforms alone; for the package of reforms, the results were similar. Id. at A1 :62 . The FSA also showed breakdowns by borrower type in the subperiods . Id. at A1 :41 -42, A1:63-64.

Id at A1 :65 .

Id at A1 :2 . Another disclaimer: “No amount of quantification would remove the need to make such a judgement . We illustrate, however, our quantification of the tradeoff. This should not be interpreted as providing a precise measure of well-being effects, but rather as supporting some reasonable assumptions about the relative weight attached to different positive and negative effects, and illustrating that such relative weights might support different judgements .” Id. at A1 :80 .

Id at A1 :5 . While the FSA believed those judgments “are best informed” by its CBA/FR, it presented no evidence to show that was true, or if so, how. Id.

Id at A1 :3 .

Eg. , CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 13 (rebutting the belief that “quantifying the expected benefits of a regulation is impossible,” instead claiming that “rigorous cost-benefit analysis is not only feasible but has been successfully employed by regulators both in the United States and abroad”).

John Y Campbell et al., Consumer Financial Protection , 25 J. Econ. Persp . 91, 98-99 (2011).

Luigi Zingales , The Future of Securities Regulation , 47 J Acct. Res . 391, 393-401 (2009).

Using partially quantified CBA to generate bounds is sometimes offered as a solution to the problematic output of CBA See, e.g ., Sunstein , supra note 19, at 2 (describing that estimates of expected value are useful to identifying regulatory benefits). But bounds do not generally make quantified CBA/FR useful, for two reasons. First, estimates of bounds themselves are highly imprecise. For example, even the “easily” quantified subsets of costs for many financial rules, such as the direct costs of SOX 404, have wide confidence intervals; for SOX 404, they range from $400,000 to $4 million per firm per year, and that range has changed over time. See supra text accompanying notes 164- 167 . The lower bound on a lower bound (here, that is, $400,000) is all that partial quantified CBA can typically produce to guide policy judgment. Second, and more importantly, also as shown in Part III, when estimates of costs and benefits are both highly uncertain and imprecise, as is common in CBA/FR, the lower bound on the lower bound that can emerge from partial quantified CBA may not be a meaningful aid to policy judgment. If we know, for example, that a subset of costs can be estimated at $2.2 billion, plus or minus $1.8 billion, but we do know the benefits, a CBA advocate would argue that we have advanced the analysis because now we know that unless the benefits exceed the lower bound of the lower bound (that is, $400 million), the rule is not justified. But if any expert would have already had a prior judgment that the unquantifiable costs are likely to be an order of magnitude larger than $400 million, we have not significantly advanced the analysis, because we already knew benefits would have to be more than $400 million (indeed, more than $4 billion—an order of magnitude larger than $400 million). Quantification of the lower bound of the lower bound of the subset of costs may look precise (it produces a number), but it has not in fact improved our bottom-line estimate of the net benefits and costs, because our rough estimate of the benefits would already have had to be far higher before considering the rule. Put differently, only when partial quantification produces a lower bound on a lower bound on costs that is surprisingly high (or vice versa, in the case of bounds on benefits) will the exercise aid policymaking judgment.

Compare, eg. , Sunstein , The Cost-Benefit State , supra note 11, at 20-21 (advocating a “suitably devised system of CBA,” albeit with caveats), with Sinden , supra note 42, at 191-95 (critiquing the use of cost-benefit analysis).

See, eg. , Sunstein , supra note 36, at 2289 (“A skeptic might conclude that because the range of uncertainty [about the net costs and benefits of a regulation designed to reduce arsenic intake] is so large, any number at all could be justified and the ultimate decision is essentially political or based on ‘values.’ This view is not exactly wrong, but it should not be taken as a convincing challenge to CBA.”). Even the arsenic rule had considerably simpler potential effects on welfare than several of the case studies reviewed in Part III (for example, SOX 404 or the Volcker Rule).

See supra text accompanying notes 373-375

Compare Cliff Asness et al, Open Letter to Ben Bernanke , Wall St. J. : Real Time Econ. (Nov. 15, 2010, 12:01 AM), http://blogs.wsj.com/economics/2010/11/15/open-letter-to-ben-bernanke [http://perma.cc/3VKA-UL8W] (posting an open letter from multiple economists, including former Chairman of Council of Economic Advisors, former Director of the Congressional Budget Office, former Senior Economist of the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, and former Deputy Assistant Treasury Secretary, among others, stating that “[ w]e believe the Federal Reserve’s large-scale asset purchase plan (so-called ‘quantitative easing’) . . . risk[s] currency debasement and inflation, and we do not think they will achieve the Fed’s objective of promoting employment”), with Reply to Open Letter to Ben Bernanke from Federal Reserve Spokeswoman , Wall St. J. : Real Time Econ. (Nov. 15, 2010, 12:01 AM) , http://blogs.wsj.com/economics/2010/11/15/open-letter-to-ben-bernanke [http://perma.cc/3VKA-UL8W] (defending the Federal Open Market Committee’s “recent actions”—that is, “quantitative easing”—as reflecting the Federal Reserve’s “Congressionally-mandated objectives [of] promot [ ing ] increased employment and price stability”). See also supra notes 330-335 (noting disagreements among economists over whether an increase in bank capital requirements will reduce socially beneficial lending).

See Cass R Sunstein , The Real World of Cost-Benefit Analysis: Thirty-Six Questions (and Almost as Many Answers) , 114 Colum. L. Rev. 167, 185 (2014) (citing 75 Fed. Reg. 76,186, 76,238). The proposed rule was adopted on March 31, 2014. See NHTSA Announces Final Rule Requiring Rear Visibility Technology , Nat’l Highway Traffic & Safety Admin. (Mar. 31, 2014) , http://1.usa.gov/1fKTYZA [ http://perma.cc/EJS6-C2FN ].

The DOT’s CBA is confusing (and perhaps in error) in its presentation of cost estimates, 75 Fed Reg. 76,237 (Table 15 and text); 75 Fed. Reg. 76,240 (Table 19 and text), in that it presents both a “primary estimate” and a “high estimate” of costs that are higher when using a 7% discount rate than when using a 3% discount rate, and the text of the rule does not refer to the numbers in the tables. It is also of note that rather than monetizing a cost of a child’s life differently from that of an adult, and then using the numbers so estimated in its analysis, it used a conventional value of an adult life, concluded that its quantified CBA produced a net cost, but then adopted the rule anyway based on what it determined was the non-quantifiable additional value of a child’s life. Id. at 76,238-39.

M Marsili , Toy Models and Stylized Realities , 55 Eur. Physical J. 169, 173 (2007).

An exception is climate change, where the effects of US. regulations will depend upon how other governments cope with climate change. Quantitative CBA may for that and other reasons be less useful for coping with climate change than for regulations responding to less world-threatening problems. See Pindyck , supra note 226 .

Paul A Tipler , Physics f or Scientists and Engineers 336-37 (4th ed. 1999) (relating gravitational constant to the force of gravity at various depths).

Other physical constants relevant to non-financial domains include the magnetic constant, the electric constant, the mass of a proton, the gas constant, the speed of light, Planck’s constant, etc

Eugene F Fama & Kenneth R. French, Disappearing Dividends: Changing Firm Characteristics or Lower Propensity to Pay ? , 60 J. Fin. Econ. 3 (2001); Zingales , supra note 420, at 392. More companies are now paying dividends again, following the financial crisis, partly as a result of the extremely low interest rate environment created by quantitative easing by the Fed.

Fin Crisis Inquiry Comm’n , The Financial Crisis Inquiry Report 38-51 (2011).

Marsili , supra note 426 , at 173

Larry Tribe made the same point in this journal forty years ago when discussing CBA of environmental regulation Laurence H. Tribe, Ways Not To Think About Plastic Trees: New Foundations for Environmental Law , 83 Yale L.J. 1315, 1322 (1974) (“[ E] ven before anyone is very good at the task of attaching shadow prices to varying levels of constraints as elusive as ecological diversity, the attempt to attach them rather than simply incorporating such constraints in an all-or-nothing fashion should lead to better decision processes even if not better outcomes.”). I thank Duncan Kennedy for the reference.

See Chamber of Commerce v SEC , 443 F.3d 890 (D.C. Cir. 2006); Chamber of Commerce v. SEC , 412 F.3d 133 (D.C. Cir. 2005); see also CCMC Report , supra note 6, at 30 (characterizing the costs as “minor”); supra notes 18, 89-102 and accompanying text.

This was the view of none other than Douglas Ginsburg (now on the DC. Circuit, author of the Business Roundtable decision, see supra notes 103-126 and accompanying text), writing about his experience as the first head of OIRA from 1984 to 1985. See Christopher C. DeMuth & Douglas H. Ginsburg, White House Review of Agency Rulemaking , 99 Harv . L. Rev. 1075, 1085-86 (1986) (“The private nature of the regulatory review process [i.e., OIRA’s review of executive agency rulemaking] has been a strength . . . because . . . it can flourish only if the agency head or his delegate, and OMB as the president’s delegate, are free to discuss frankly the merits of a regulatory proposal. . . . The administration’s deliberative process would be significantly compromised if the preliminary rounds in any [interagency] disagreement were routinely publicized.”). DeMuth and Ginsburg acknowledge that private interagency review suffers from a legitimacy problem—it makes it hard for OIRA to rebut allegations that it acts to smuggle politics or private interests into the review process, out of the public’s eye—but they go on to argue that the problem is more apparent than real and in any event justified by the benefits of the process. Id. at 1086-87.

See supra note 134 and accompanying text

See Alan B Morrison, The Administrative Procedure Act: A Living and Responsive Law , 72 Va. L. Rev. 253, 256 (1986) (“[ R] ulemakings are often more controversial than adjudications [under the APA], whose very processes are hidden from outsiders.”).

Eg. , Nat’l Ass’n of Mfrs. v. SEC, 956 F. Supp. 2d 43, 46 (D.D.C. 2013) (upholding an SEC rule promulgated under section 1502 of the Dodd-Frank Act, which directed the agency “to develop and promulgate a rule requiring greater transparency and disclosure regarding the use of ‘conflict minerals’ coming out of the DRC and its neighboring countries”), aff’d in part , 748 F.3d 359 (D.C. Cir. 2014). This consequence appears to be a novel or at least recent dysfunction in the administrative state. See Jacob E. Gersen & Anne Joseph O’Connell, Deadlines in Administrative Law , 156 U. Pa. L. Rev. 923, 926 (2008) (“Because narrow delegations with extensive substantive restrictions would eliminate agency discretion and expertise in policymaking, it is rare that Congress specifies the actual content or substance of agency decisions.”); cf. Michael Herz , Judicial Textualism Meets Congressional Micromanagement: A Potential Collision in Clean Air Interpretation , 16 Harv . Envtl . L. Rev. 175, 179 (1992) (arguing that in environmental regulation, judicial deference to regulatory discretion absent statutory specificity had created incentives for Congress to impose specific mandates as the best way to control agencies).

Cf Vermeule , supra note 9 (critiquing judicial review of agency decisions under conditions of uncertainty).

See id at 2-3 for a different but complementary argument that courts should be more deferential to agencies in contexts requiring arbitrary decisions.

For evidence that judicial review of agency action outside the financial regulatory context is motivated by politics and judicial ideology, despite nominal legal standards requiring deference and permitting court intervention only if the agency acts “arbitrarily” or “capriciously,” see supra note 127 and accompanying text

Kraus & Raso , supra note 12, at 338-42; see also Fisch , supra note 116, at 718-21 (discussing the application of the Government in the Sunshine Act, 5 US.C. § 522(b) (2012), to the SEC).

Freedom of Information Act, 5 US.C. § 552 (2012).

See sources cited supra note 81

See sources cited supra note 82

See supra text accompanying notes 86-87

Kraus & Raso , supra note 12, at 341

See OMB Guidance, supra note 20, at 4-15

CBA/FR advocates, see, eg. , CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 14, rightly point to the SEC’s pilot program on short sale rules, which randomly exempted a stratified sample from new rules for purposes of evaluating the rules’ effects in a statistically reliable way. See Office of Econ. Analysis , Economic Analysis of the Short Sale Price Restrictions Under the Regulation SHO Pilot , Sec. & Exch. Comm’n (2007), http://www.sec.gov/news/studies/2007/regshopilot020607.pdf [http://perma.cc/EE3U-VAUD].

CCMR Report , supra note 4, at 9

I take up the task of making such proposals in a related paper See Coates , supra note 10 .

  • Contributors

Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and Implications

case study on financial regulation

John Coates is the John F. Cogan, Jr. Professor of Law and Economics at Harvard Law School.

The 2010 Dodd-Frank Act mandated over 200 new rules, bringing renewed attention to the use of cost-benefit analysis (CBA) in financial regulation. CBA proponents and industry advocates have criticized the independent financial regulatory agencies for failing to base the new rules on CBA, and many have sought to mandate judicial review of quantified CBA (examples of “white papers” advocating CBA of financial regulation can be found here and here ). An increasing number of judicial challenges to financial regulations have been brought in the D.C. Circuit under existing law, many successful, and bills have been introduced in Congress to mandate CBA of financial regulation .

In this paper,  Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and Implications , I develop detailed case studies that collectively show that precise, reliable, quantified CBA is simply not feasible in a representative sample of six significant financial regulations. Instead, efforts to quantify CBA routinely require multiple, subjective, contestable judgments, producing what can only be called “guesstimates”—extremely wide ranges of equally defensible net costs and benefits—so wide that the effort cannot meaningfully “guide” assessments of the rules. Because finance is central to the economy, because it is social and political, and because it is non-stationary, regulation of finance and financial markets is different in kind from many other kinds of regulation, which focus on activities that can be more reliably studied. As a result, judicial review of quantified CBA in the financial context is more likely to camouflage discretionary choices than to discipline agencies or promote democracy.

The paper first clarifies the meaning of CBA. CBA is often used to mean policy analysis, but also to mean types of laws mandating the use of CBA or providing for judicial review of CBA or its inputs. CBA is also sometimes used to describe a general conceptual framework for evaluating regulations, roughly amounting to applied welfare economics, which is a sensible framework for general policy analysis, but it is also sometimes expected to produce specific quantified estimates of the effects of a rule—“quantified CBA.” Finally, CBA is often viewed as a clearly good thing as a policy matter—enhancing transparency and democracy, and disciplining regulators—but the history of CBA suggests that it can also produce a darker mix of effects, including rent-seeking, increases in regulatory discretion, and reductions in transparency. The paper then reviews current law of CBA relevant to financial agencies, and critiques the recent spate of D.C. Circuit decisions striking down regulations on the supposed ground of inadequate CBA.

The core of the paper is a close examination of what efforts to quantify CBA might produce, or in two cases what such efforts did produce, as applied to six representative and major financial regulations:

  • 1. The SEC’s disclosure rules under Sarbanes-Oxley Section 404,
  • 2. The SEC’s aborted mutual fund governance reforms,
  • 3. Basel III’s heightened capital and liquidity requirements for banks,
  • 4. The Volcker rule,
  • 5. The SEC’s cross-border swap proposals, and
  • 6. The FSA’s mortgage market reforms.

In the case studies, the paper attempts to advance the substantive project of quantitative CBA of financial regulation itself, by specifying in more detail than prior research how CBA could be applied in specific contexts, and by more carefully describing, clarifying, and specifying sources of sensitivity of the results of quantified CBA in each study. The primary general conclusion of the case studies is that CBA of such rules cannot be reliably and precisely quantified with current research methods.

Rather, CBA for major financial regulations entails (a) causal inferences that are unreliable under standard regulatory conditions; (b) using problematic data, and/or (c) the same contestable, assumption-sensitive macroeconomic and/or political modeling used to make monetary policy, which even CBA advocates would exempt from CBA law. While CBA is a useful conceptual framework for financial regulation, and quantified CBA is a worthy long-term research goal, CBA is not capable of disciplining regulatory analysis in its current state. Instead, CBA should be conducted only to the extent the relevant financial agencies choose to do so. For the near future, at least, decisions of when and how to conduct CBA in the financial regulation inevitably remain in the realm of judgment—and subject to ordinary political discipline. Neither Congress nor the Courts can force such decisions into the realm of science, and attempts to do so will be more political than legal, and do more to obscure than enlighten the public about the judgments financial regulation requires.

The full paper is available for download here .

Supported By:

case study on financial regulation

Subscribe or Follow

Program on corporate governance advisory board.

  • William Ackman
  • Peter Atkins
  • Kerry E. Berchem
  • Richard Brand
  • Daniel Burch
  • Arthur B. Crozier
  • Renata J. Ferrari
  • John Finley
  • Carolyn Frantz
  • Andrew Freedman
  • Byron Georgiou
  • Joseph Hall
  • Jason M. Halper
  • David Millstone
  • Theodore Mirvis
  • Maria Moats
  • Erika Moore
  • Morton Pierce
  • Philip Richter
  • Marc Trevino
  • Steven J. Williams
  • Daniel Wolf

HLS Faculty & Senior Fellows

  • Lucian Bebchuk
  • Robert Clark
  • John Coates
  • Stephen M. Davis
  • Allen Ferrell
  • Jesse Fried
  • Oliver Hart
  • Howell Jackson
  • Kobi Kastiel
  • Reinier Kraakman
  • Mark Ramseyer
  • Robert Sitkoff
  • Holger Spamann
  • Leo E. Strine, Jr.
  • Guhan Subramanian
  • Roberto Tallarita

Back to Faculty Bibliography

John C. Coates, Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and Implications , 124 Yale L. J. 882 (2015).

Abstract: Some members of Congress, the D.C. Circuit, and the legal academy are promoting a particular, abstract form of cost-benefit analysis for financial regulation: judicially enforced quantification. How would CBA work in practice, if applied to specific, important, representative rules, and what is the alternative? Detailed case studies of six rules—(1) disclosure rules under Sarbanes-Oxley section 404; (2) the SEC’s mutual fund governance reforms; (3) Basel III’s heightened capital requirements for banks; (4) the Volcker Rule; (5) the SEC’s cross-border swap proposals; and (6) the FSA’s mortgage reforms—show that precise, reliable, quantified CBA remains unfeasible. Quantified CBA of such rules can be no more than “guesstimated,” as it entails (a) causal inferences that are unreliable under standard regulatory conditions; (b) the use of problematic data; and/or (c) the same contestable, assumption-sensitive macroeconomic and/or political modeling used to make monetary policy, which even CBA advocates would exempt from CBA laws. Expert judgment remains an inevitable part of what advocates label “gold-standard” quantified CBA, because finance is central to the economy, is social and political, and is non-stationary. Judicial review of quantified CBA can be expected to do more to camouflage discretionary choices than to discipline agencies or promote democracy.

  • --> Login or Sign Up

Harvard Law School  The Case Studies

  • Harvard Law Case Studies A-Z

Consumer Financial Protection Bureau: Responding to the PHH Litigation

Cordray speaking on behalf of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau

Ryan M. Johansen under the supervision of Howell Jackson

Share This Article

  • Custom Field #1
  • Custom Field #2
  • Similar Products

Product Description

Accessibility

To obtain accessible versions of our products for use by those with disabilities, please contact the HLS Case Studies Program at [email protected] or +1-617-496-1316.

Copyright Information

Please note that each purchase of this product entitles the purchaser to one download and use.  If you need multiple copies, please purchase the number of copies you need. For more information, see  Copying Your Case Study .

Product Videos

Custom field, product reviews, write a review.

case study on financial regulation

Find Similar Products by Category

Recommended.

cars parked on a street

Ames’ Auto Insurance Regulations — Racial Disparities in Insurance Premiums

large pile of money

Cost-Benefit Analysis at the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau

Howell Jackson and Kelley O'Mara

calculator, expense sheet, and pen on a desk

Federal Preemption of State Consumer Protection Laws: The Office of the Comptroller of the Currency's Dodd-Frank Act Implementation Rules

Melanie Berdecia and Dylan Aluise under supervision of Howell Jackson

peer to peer diagram

Lending Club: 2008

Anooshree Sinha and Corrine Snow under the supervision of Howell Jackson

  • Related Products

Financial Inclusion and Virtual Bank in the Era of Digitalization: A Regulatory Case Study in Hong Kong

  • First Online: 14 May 2024

Cite this chapter

case study on financial regulation

  • Sau Wai Law 2  

Implicit in the promise of virtual banks is the mission of promoting financial inclusion in Hong Kong, through offering increased accessibility and brand-new customer experiences through the internet, which are said to be easier, more personalized, and customer-centered. Nevertheless, while regulators encourage using technological solutions to reduce barriers to access and friction, there is a need to strike a balance between promoting technological innovations, protecting customers, and enhancing the returns to investors. Through the content analysis of the recent speeches and guidelines from Hong Kong Monetary Authority and the financial inclusion report from the United Kingdom, it is observed that the regulation of virtual banks in Hong Kong tends to focus predominately on promoting technological innovations. This is unlikely to be sufficient to replicate the trust and confidence in the traditional banking environments due to the lack of consideration to incorporate human factors between banks and clients. This paper articulates the importance of improving the following three areas which could be incorporated into future amendments to future regulatory guidelines: First is to review and accommodate the differences in the bank-customer relationship under the new interaction model. Second is to enhance transparency and disclosure of the technology involved in virtual bank operation. Third is to provide greater assistance to customers to improve their comprehensiveness of the increasing complexity of bank operation, particularly for those who do not have high financial literacy and those who might be discouraged from making an enquiry due to lack of human interaction with the banks. These would improve accessibility and make a meaningful impact to financial inclusion through the launch of virtual banks in Hong Kong.

Cite as : Sau-Wai Law (2021). Financial Inclusion and Virtual Bank in the Era of Digitalisation: A Regulatory Case Study in Hong Kong. SocioEconomic Challenges , 5 (3), 81-91. https://doi.org/10.21272/sec.5(3).81-91.2021 .

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Institutional subscriptions

Department for Work and Pensions. (2020). UK financial inclusion report 2019–2020 . https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/935985/Financial_Inclusion_Report_2020.pdf . Accessed 28 June 2021

Gov.uk. (2017). Government response to Lords Select Committee final report on financial exclusion . Cm 9524. https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/657145/Response_to_Financial_Exclusion_Committee_web.pdf . Accessed 1 Sep 2021

HKSAR. (2019). The Hong Kong poverty situation report 2019 . https://www.povertyrelief.gov.hk/eng/pdf/Hong_Kong_Poverty_Situation_Report_2019.pdf Accessed: 13 Aug 2021

Hong Kong Monetary Authority. (2014). https://www.hkma.gov.hk/media/eng/doc/key-information/pressrelease/2013/20131028e2_annex2.pdf

Hong Kong Monetary Authority. (2016). De-risking and financial inclusion, HKMA. https://www.hkma.gov.hk/media/eng/doc/key-information/guidelines-and-circular/2016/20160908e1.pdf Accessed 3 Aug 2021.

Hong Kong Monetary Authority. (2018). A revised Guideline on authorization of virtual banks, Issued on 30 May 2018. https://www.hkma.gov.hk/media/eng/doc/key-information/press-release/2018/20180530e3a2.pdf Accessed 26 June 2021.

Hong Kong Monetary Authority (2019a). Feedback from thematic review of AIs’ application of AML/CFT Controls in the SME Segment”, 14 June 2019, Hong Kong Monetary Authority. Available at https://www.hkma.gov.hk/media/eng/doc/key-information/guidelines-and-circular/2019/20190614e2.pdf . Accessed 3 Aug 2021.

Hong Kong Monetary Authority. (2019b). Granting of virtual banking licences, 27 Mar 2019 HKMA Speech . https://www.hkma.gov.hk/eng/news-and-media/press-releases/2019/03/20190327-3/ Accessed 12 Aug 2021.

Hong Kong Monetary Authority. (2019c). Keynote speech at the HKAB & HKIB distinguished speaker Luncheon Norman T.L. Chan, Chief Executive, 26 Sep 2019 Hong Kong Monetary Authority . https://www.hkma.gov.hk/eng/news-and-media/speeches/2019/09/20190926-2/ . Accessed 1 Sept 2021.

Hong Kong Monetary Authority. (2020a). Guideline on minimum criteria for authorization” issued by the HKMA under section 16(10) of the Banking Ordinance. https://www.hkma.gov.hk/media/eng/doc/key-information/guidelines-and-circular/guideline/g15.pdf . Accessed 26 June 2021.

Hong Kong Monetary Authority. (2020b). Guide to authorization” . HKMA. https://www.hkma.gov.hk/eng/regulatory-resources/regulatory-guides/guide-to-authorization/ Accessed 26 June 2021

Hong Kong Monetary Authority. (2020c). Guideline on banking services for persons with intellectual disabilities of Hong Kong Association of Banks” , HKMA. https://www.hkma.gov.hk/media/eng/doc/key-information/guidelines-and-circular/2020/20201215e1.pdf . Accessed 3 Aug 2021.

Hong Kong Monetary Authority. (2021). Virtual bank . https://www.hkma.gov.hk/eng/key-functions/banking/banking-regulatory-and-supervisory-regime/virtual-banks/ . Accessed 12 Aug 2021

House of Commons Briefing Paper. (2017). Financial inclusion (Exclusion)”] (15 December 2017) at 4 . https://researchbriefings.files.parliament.uk/documents/SN03197/SN03197.pdf . Accessed 13 Aug 2021

Law S. W., & Wong, D. (2021). Could increasing regulatory focus realise the inclusive potential of virtual banks ? pp. 38–43. Banking Today. https://member.hkib.org/BankingToday/magazine/vqxe2023cvzm_BT_Jul2021/mobile/index.html Accessed 11 Aug 2021

Lee, E. (2021). Digital financial inclusion: observations and insights from Hong Kong’s virtual banks.  Law and Contemporary Problems ,  84 (1), 95–113. https://scholarship.law.duke.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=4987&context=lcp . Accessed 11 Aug 2021

Park, C. Y., & Mercado, R. (2015). Financial inclusion, poverty, and income inequality in developing Asia.  Asian Development Bank Economics Working Paper Series , (426). https://www.adb.org/sites/default/files/publication/153143/ewp-426.pdf Accessed 1 Sept 2021

Sustainable Development Goal. (2021). Take action for the sustainable development goal: The United Nations . https://www.un.org/sustainabledevelopment/sustainable-development-goals/ . Accessed 12 August 2021

The World Bank. (2017). The global findex database, The World Bank group . https://globalfindex.worldbank.org/ . Accessed 13 Aug 2021.

The World Bank. (2021). Financial inclusion . https://www.worldbank.org/en/topic/financialinclusion/overview . Accessed 13 Aug 2021.

UNCDF. (2021). Financial Inclusion and the SDGs . https://www.uncdf.org/financial-inclusion-and-the-sdgs . Accessed 13 Aug 2021.

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to Liliana Lopa of her guidance in publishing this article. I am also obliged to Mr. Davyd Wong for his helpful insights.

Self-funded.

Author information

Authors and affiliations.

School of Law, University of Reading, Reading, Berkshire, UK

Sau Wai Law

You can also search for this author in PubMed   Google Scholar

Contributions

Conceptualization, Sau-Wai Law; data curation, Sau-Wai Law; formal analysis, Sau-Wai Law; funding acquisition, Sau-Wai Law; investigation, Sau-Wai Law; methodology, Sau-Wai Law; project administration, Sau-Wai Law; resources, Sau-Wai Law; software, Sau-Wai Law; supervision, Sau-Wai Law; validation, Sau-Wai Law; visualization, Sau-Wai Law; writing—original draft, Sau-Wai Law; writing—review and editing, Sau-Wai Law.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Sau Wai Law .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2024 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Law, S.W. (2024). Financial Inclusion and Virtual Bank in the Era of Digitalization: A Regulatory Case Study in Hong Kong. In: Financial Inclusion, Technology and Virtual Banking. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-97-1127-7_2

Download citation

DOI : https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-97-1127-7_2

Published : 14 May 2024

Publisher Name : Springer, Singapore

Print ISBN : 978-981-97-1126-0

Online ISBN : 978-981-97-1127-7

eBook Packages : Business and Management Business and Management (R0)

Share this chapter

Anyone you share the following link with will be able to read this content:

Sorry, a shareable link is not currently available for this article.

Provided by the Springer Nature SharedIt content-sharing initiative

  • Publish with us

Policies and ethics

  • Find a journal
  • Track your research

Cashing Out a Special Relationship?: Trends Toward Reconciliation Between Financial Regulation and Administrative Law

  • February 2017
  • See full issue

Like an optical illusion or an Escher drawing, the relationship between financial regulation and administrative law is intricate and prone to reflect one’s perspective. 1 From a distance, the fields may appear entirely in sync, even derivative. Financial regulation — legal structures governing markets, institutions, and actors — is formally bound by the procedural constraints of administrative law and that law limits agency action. 2 Yet on closer approach, the two show signs of serious inconsistencies. 3 The day-to-day practice of financial regulation operates relatively unimpeded by major elements of administrative procedure, and the larger commitments of administrative law — visions of ordered agency policymaking and expansive judicial engagement — remain largely unrealized. 4 Closest up, the fields offer stark contrasts on their first principles: each locates itself in divergent economic and political ecosystems and calls for separate end goals. 5

Juxtaposing financial regulation with administrative law thus seems to offer a paradox: the fields are coordinate in their basic descriptions but vaguely detached in day-to-day activities and misaligned on their points of deep logic. Perhaps for this reason, scholars have often struggled to understand how financial regulation fits within the administrative law scheme — whether it represents administrative principles applied to a transformative extreme, or else is a curious exception to the general norm. 6 Regardless of the reason, the result is a financial regulatory system that appears distinctive from many other forms of regulatory law: it is faster moving, opaque in its decisionmaking, and highly oriented to preventing crisis — at the cost of some inconsistency with general administrative procedure.

Recently, however, a new leveling wind has begun to blow. In a number of cases at the boundaries of the two fields, courts have applied rigid constraints of administrative law to resolve relatively amorphous financial regulatory issues. These cases express a strong set of presumptions about how financial regulation should be conceptualized and administered. 7 They reject views of financial regulation as demanding a tailored approach, and instead seek to cover the field with off-the-rack administrative law doctrines. Underlying this movement are two broad yet congruent thoughts: a heightened concern for a perceptibly overpowering financial regulatory apparatus 8 and increased confidence in the methods of administrative law, most notably a heavily monetized cost-benefit analysis (CBA). 9 The result is an approach treating financial regulatory action as largely indistinct from any other subject of agency policymaking.

Yet this impulse toward a one-size-fits-all framework eludes the reasons why approaches to financial regulation have and should be tailored to their circumstances. This normalization trend applies administrative tools to situations outside the scope of their design and contradicts the major principles underlying the modern financial regulatory state. 10 The result is both overinclusive in limiting necessary exercises of regulatory power and underinclusive in confounding the areas of most pointed concern. Rather than attempting to channel the anxieties generated by regulatory policymaking through such an untailored approach, the impulses driving the normalization trend should be realized in a more nuanced and limited form. 11

Part I of this Note outlines the conceptual relationship between administrative law and financial regulation. Part II grounds the trend in history. Part III identifies the countertrend of financial regulatory normalization, as found in three recent decisions straddling the administrative-financial regulatory line: Business Roundtable v. SEC , 12 State National Bank of Big Spring v. Lew , 13 and Metlife, Inc. v. Financial Stability Oversight Council . 14 Part IV discusses the latent concerns behind this development and suggests reasons why a more tailored approach acknowledges anxieties and better achieves the intended ends.

I. The Uneasy Relationship Between Financial Regulation and Administrative Law

Delineating between financial regulation and administrative law proves a surprisingly involved task, not least because each of the fields contains both a central core and a larger periphery. 15 On the broadest level of definition, nonetheless, one might see few inconsistencies and perhaps major connections. The top-level boundaries of administrative law are marked by issues of procedure, with a matter called administrative if its decisionmaking is sufficiently developed. 16 In turn, the basic definition of financial regulation involves questions of substance, with boundaries based on the nature of the thing regulated. 17 To be sure, the latter’s limits may be rather blurry: while matters like banking, insurance, or investment management are clearly within the scope, matters like securities, pensions, or consumer credit raise questions. 18 Nonetheless, at least on principle, these two definitional questions seem entirely congruent. One thus might view financial regulation as a clear subset of administrative law akin to environmental law: realizing its policy through administrative means. 19

Even at this degree of highest definition, it is striking not how much financial regulation incorporates administrative procedure, but how much it does not. For example, few Federal Reserve Board decisions face judicial review in the form contemplated by the Administrative Procedure Act 20 (APA). The substantial role of private financial regulators complicates public administrative law’s generally exclusive status. 21 Most illustratively, the Chevron doctrine is nearly entirely absent from the financial regulatory sphere. 22 One might respond that the APA includes explicit allowance for exceptions, 23 and thus the fact of financial regulation’s day-to-day practices does not necessarily imply its independence from that broader law.

Yet such responses may miss a larger point. Legal fields are not just assortments of doctrine but also larger statements about the world that doctrine shapes. 24 In administrative law, the broad vision includes a formalized policymaking process, restrictions on agency decisionmaking, and an expansive role for judicial review. 25 On this conception, administrative law represents carefully balanced compromises about means of crafting policy, and legal doctrines seek to realize those commitments. 26 That deep view may even sometimes conflict with its shallower expressions: for example, the standing doctrine implied by the APA differs from that of current law. 27 An understanding of financial regulation as coextensive with the APA has a more difficult time incorporating this result than one that views the law as an instrumental means to larger (here, separation of powers) values.

The broader vision of financial regulation takes a different and somewhat contradictory tone. Financial regulation is marked by a strongly outcomes-focused attitude, defining itself by problems to be solved rather than abstract values to be realized. 28 It thus preferences quickness over deliberation, willingness to decide based on limited information, and a general faith in market behavior. 29 Where administrative law seeks to distribute powers among government branches, financial regulation aims to secure regulators’ authority against regulated entities. 30 If the key anxiety of administrative law is that power might be exercised arbitrarily, the worry of financial regulation is that no power will be exercised at all. 31

Thus, in many ways, the practice of financial regulation shows as much variability as overlap with administrative law. 32 Take the process of day-to-day banking supervision. These procedures tend toward extreme informality, “enforced through phone calls and jawboning, rather than through enforcement orders and prohibition.” 33 Moreover, the standards for what such decisions entail may be loose or even somewhat irregularly formed. 34 Under the view of administrative law, this conduct might seem the definition of impermissibly arbitrary action. For a financial regulator, by contrast, concerns about accountability and transparency pale in comparison to those of context: the best decision tomorrow might be worse than a more arbitrary one today. 35

II. Historical Roots of a Controversy

Financial regulation and administrative law have not always been so divided. Indeed, the fields were largely coterminous in their nascence. 36 Both fields are, of course, children of the New Deal era, where administrative law developed to execute the budding financial regulatory system. 37 Understanding how the systems evolved and grew apart thus sheds light on the scope of controversy today.

Even eighty years on, “the basic financial regulatory structure is a New Deal legacy.” 38 Scholars have told, and overtold, the story of how the U.S. financial regulatory system evolved as a reaction against the excesses of the 1920s, an attempt to stem an intractable economic downturn, and an effort to leverage the mediating power of government toward broad societal benefit. 39 The New Deal years saw the creation of many of the most prominent of today’s agencies: the Federal Deposit Insurance Corporation (FDIC), the Federal Reserve’s Open Market Committee, and, of course, the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC). 40 Yet while these agencies enjoyed new substantive powers, arguably the more important development was the growth in means of their administrative decisionmaking. 41 Where previous financial regulators enjoyed relatively limited policymaking fora, New Deal–era agencies enjoyed both numerous new procedural powers as well as newfound freedom to choose among them. 42 Indeed, at the end of the period, the Supreme Court famously upheld agencies’ power to make such procedural choices as instrumental to their mission. 43

In administrative law, the New Deal era was likewise a time of ferment, and the 1946 passage of the APA largely reflected lessons of New Deal–era practice. 44 An overwhelming amount of this formation occurred in the financial regulatory space. Many major intellectual influences in administrative law came out of a financial regulatory background, and subsequent work has highlighted the degree to which early conceptions of administrative law reflected financial regulatory practice. 45 Take, for instance, the paradigmatic example of Professor James Landis, early SEC Commissioner and author of the canonical The Administrative Process . 46 Landis’s skepticism about separation of powers was almost certainly informed by the SEC’s expansive powers to combine authorities — a combination Landis viewed as essential to effective policymaking. 47 Nor was Landis an outlier in these views; indeed, one retrospective of the period has emphasized the “consistent pattern of deference to the SEC” in validating the agency’s design. 48

The New Deal–era connection between administrative law and financial regulation succeeded largely on the basis of the former’s concession to the latter’s regulatory needs. Financial regulation existed — arguably quite successfully — with a relatively thin layer of administrative law oversight. 49 For Landis and other New Dealers, the purpose of administrative law was an instrumental good rather than an end goal: the field aimed to authorize greater discretion than previous legal regimes had enabled. To be sure, history also suggests that thin review need not imply total judicial abdication. 50 Nonetheless, the New Deal indicates that coordination between financial regulation and administrative law proves most successful when financial regulation enjoys full procedural choice, even over administrative law concerns for accountability and standardization in policymaking form.

Subsequent years have seen the substantive relationships between administrative law and financial regulation — the former shaping itself to the substantive needs of the latter — drift increasingly apart. Scholars have offered explanations for why this movement occurred, including economic developments demanding new financial approaches, shifts in administrative rulemaking focus from economic to social risks, and developments in the nature of legal scholarship. 51

That degree of disconnect may be most evident in the departure from the New Deal–era conception that financial regulation and administrative law enjoyed no substantial tradeoffs. 52 During the New Deal era, agencies portrayed the substance of regulations as involving choices of normative values, while administrative law mostly involved ministerial considerations regarding the execution of those wishes. 53 Today, by contrast, administrative law is often tagged with political connotations, as it appears to implement the vision of how government should relate to affected parties. 54 Moreover, one increasingly prevalent view of financial regulation casts it as a largely apolitical effort; neither bankers nor their regulators benefit from a market crash, after all. 55 One might push back on that argument, pointing to concerns like agency capture or somnolence. 56 The point is not that arguments for discretion ignore these concerns; rather, they evaluate them as less harmful than the cost of crippled policymaking. 57

The result, at least until recently, was that while financial regulation engaged with some doctrines of current administrative law, the fields willingly disengaged on others. Take, for example, the use of international standards. As Professor David Zaring has noted, an increasing amount of regulatory policy comes through internationally negotiated agreements: accords on proper means for evaluating anticompetition or emissions standards, for example. 58 Such efforts raise substantial domestic concerns about appointments and delegation, and these agreements have made little headway with most regulatory agencies. 59 Yet financial regulators have had no trouble incorporating such agreements into their work, and where challenged, courts have been willing to accept a view of financial regulatory agencies as excepted from generally applicable administrative law requirements. 60 In this realm, agencies enjoy an individualized review designed for their industry and purposes, with general doctrine informing but not finalizing the law to which the agency is bound.

The financial crisis of 2008 complicates this picture. While the tumult had many fathers, one particularly strong critique blames the financial regulatory agencies’ blinkered visions for exacerbating the crisis, most notably in their perceived failure to confront an out-of-control industry. 61 The crisis also sparked a number of ancillary concerns, including a critique of so-called “revolving door” staffing, 62 and it cost agencies regulatory prestige. One might push back on the indictment, since failure in an industry is not necessarily identical to the failure of regulators. Perhaps unsurprisingly, some observers since 2008 have questioned the unique structures of financial regulation and suggested a return to the unadulterated constraints of administrative law. 63 This solution, once sublimated, is increasingly coming to the fore.

III. The Era of Convergence

A series of recent scholarly projects have attempted to reject rigid yet increasingly questionable distinctions between financial regulation and administrative law and draw them closer together once more. A limited form of this project argues that the two fields share substantial types of problems and can learn lessons from one another: administrative law in financial regulation’s ability to match structure to the crisis at hand, financial regulation in administrative law’s emphasis on creating quantifiable guideposts for judicial review. 64 A more ambitious version sees financial regulation and administrative law as almost entirely overlapping, and financial regulation benefitting from drawing upon administrative law’s relatively more defined structures. 65

It might seem that these arguments are speculative, describing a distant future. Yet a closer examination of the trends on the ground suggests that reality may be accelerating well ahead of theory. A series of recent cases at the border of administrative law and regulatory practice offers a robustly developed treatment of financial regulatory issues as largely administrative in form and rejects a more focused financial regulatory approach. If the era of financial regulatory normalization is approaching, these cases are its vanguard.

Business Roundtable v. SEC involved a challenge to the SEC’s recently promulgated proxy access rule, an apparently technical subject with larger immediate challenges and even more significant implications. 66 Prior to the case, new statutory authority had allowed the SEC to promulgate a rule requiring companies to streamline the process of shareholder access to proxy cards for elections to a company’s board. 67 The SEC readily promulgated an expansive new rule. 68 A number of business groups objected to this output on grounds that the regulation imposed a substantial burden for comparatively low gain. 69 While the SEC had conducted a notice-and-comment procedure and informally assessed the justifications for the regulation for itself, it had not promulgated a full CBA. 70 In part, as the SEC viewed the issue, the importance of the subject compelled quick movement: the rulemaking expressed the view that the rule would substantially promote market efficiency and might even have limited the 2008 financial crisis. 71 With such great gains apparently available, it is perhaps understandable why the SEC viewed drawbacks as obviously less significant.

The D.C. Circuit nonetheless invalidated the rule. The key to the decision was the APA’s provision that courts reject agency actions that are “arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with law.” 72 The arbitrariness here came from the agency’s refusal to conduct a fleshed out CBA. 73 The court saw that avoidance as particularly salient because it perceived a mandate that the SEC “apprise itself — and hence the public and the Congress — of the economic consequences of a proposed regulation.” 74 Notably, the court did not (and could not) find that this requirement was explicitly imposed by the Commission’s organic statute, or else by practice; rather, it constructed the mandate through reading implications of similar provisions elsewhere in the statute as authorizing the rule. 75

Much ink has been spilled over the decision in Business Roundtable , perhaps more so than for any other financial regulatory case of the past decade. Scholars have taken issue with the claim that the Commission’s CBA was limited or haphazard, pointing out that the analysis did consider the factors highlighted by the court — the court simply disagreed on the ultimate evaluation. 76 Beyond the narrow factual disputes about the decision’s internal correctness, observers have expressed even greater consternation at the highly substantive review offered by the Business Roundtable court, a form of review strongly at odds with understandings of agency expertise. 77 Where most reviews of agency actions take issue with procedural invalidity, or else with evidence so overwhelming that it makes an opposite decision arbitrary or capricious, the Business Roundtable court took the unique approach of substantively weighing for itself the factors that the agency itself had previously considered. 78

Yet perhaps the most intriguing element of Business Roundtable is the threshold assumption that CBA represents an appropriate lens for financial regulatory decisionmaking and subsequent judicial review. Professor John Coates, for example, has pointed out the mismatch between the questions CBA best evaluates and the sets of concerns that financial regulation can address. 79 As he argues, CBA functions best in places of relatively known variables, a static environment, and few externalities. Finance’s centrality to the economy, its lack of stability, and significant noneconomic implications challenge all of these conditions. 80 If there ever were a place to find CBA inapposite — or at least limited — financial regulation would appear to be it. 81

That Business Roundtable thus saw not just the possibility but the necessity of sophisticated CBA in financial regulation suggests a larger vision about the expansion of administrative law constraints to even the most distant fora. CBA has gained significant ground in administrative law, so much so that a reasonable argument exists that an agency decision not run through the matrix of CBA lacks rationality by definition. 82 In turn, advocates of CBA argue that the tool is useful both in constraining perceptibly excessive agency discretion and in laying bare otherwise obscured agency assumptions to facilitate more extensive judicial review. 83 This assertion — apparently at play in Business Roundtable — stands at striking odds with key principles of financial regulation. 84 Historically, financial regulators’ broad procedural discretion has enabled CBA adopted on a voluntary basis and only lightly reviewed later. 85 By endorsing a vision of CBA and highly substantive subsequent judicial revaluation as the default rather than the exception, Business Roundtable imposed significant barriers to regulatory policymaking, but it even more notably rejected the elements that make financial regulation distinctive.

If Business Roundtable demonstrates how the tools and coordinate assumptions of broader administrative law can be applied to financial regulatory practice to an unexpected degree, State National Bank of Big Spring v. Lew demonstrates how implicit understandings about those tools increasingly infect judicial engagement with financial regulatory decisionmaking. In the case, the eponymous bank, joined by a number of other plaintiffs, challenged new legal authorities in the Dodd-Frank Wall Street Reform and Consumer Protection Act 86 (Dodd-Frank): the Financial Stability Oversight Council (FSOC) and the Orderly Liquidation Authority (OLA). 87 The plaintiffs argued that FSOC raised significant separation of powers issues in the establishment and enforcement of its decisions. They also asserted that the OLA could result in an arbitrary exercise of government power and would thus constitute a taking of plaintiffs’ property. 88

The D.C. Circuit found for the government on entirely procedural grounds. The court avoided the challenge to FSOC’s substantive powers, since the procedural posture of the case involved firms in the same industry attempting to apply the doctrine of competitor standing — a claim the court viewed as “simply too attenuated and speculative” in these circumstances. 89 The court likewise applied doctrines of standing and ripeness, doctrines instrumental in administrative law, to reject the OLA-based challenge, perceiving that it was “premature for a court to consider the legality of how the Government might wield the [OLA] in a potential future proceeding.” 90 The court did allow the bank’s challenge to the constitutionality of the Consumer Financial Protection Bureau (CFPB) to proceed on grounds that challenges to the existence of agencies regulating the plaintiffs themselves are permissible. 91

State National Bank might seem a run-of-the-mill administrative law case, but this ordinariness is itself the point. Administrative law doctrines pose unique challenges for parties in the financial regulatory realm, so much so that they have rarely been applied in full force to many financial regulatory decisions. 92 Given the complex and often opaque nature of financial markets, showing direct connections or the nature of the harm to a legally cognizable degree of precision proves a particularly difficult task. For example, a demonstrated drop in bond prices owing to the designation may be more opaque than a factory closure. 93 Moreover, given the uncertainty inherent in those markets, it can often be difficult to predict which parties, even if nominally all under the same aegis, are actually likely to bear regulatory burdens, and which assertions of harm are merely hypothetical. 94

The traditional reconciliation of the high burdens of general administrative law with the unique circumstances of financial regulation has been a rather light and narrowly tailored application of doctrines like standing and ripeness. 95 Even if one sees State National Bank ’s procedural posture as ambitious, the multifaceted nature of financial regulation makes it difficult to draw a principled line that would distinguish this case from an unquestionably meritorious challenge. The general administrative approach may thus prove unwelcome, since the subject of financial regulation is so dissimilar to the usual administrative decisionmaking.

State National Bank thus illustrates and potentially exacerbates the difficulties that administrative law procedural doctrines have in the realm of financial regulatory action. Even prior to the case, observers had warned that such doctrines were inappropriate given the unique nature of financial regulation and worrisome policy outcomes. 96 State National Bank may accelerate these concerns. Following the decision, observers in other financial regulatory fields have noted general uncertainty about when administrative law doctrines apply at procedural stages and thus constrain agency policymaking or citizens’ rights, or whether financial regulatory procedural standards still apply. 97 One might wish to view State National Bank as a one-off case — the strangeness of its posture limiting its impact — but the assumptions implicit in the case may bear in other lights.

MetLife, Inc. v. Financial Stability Oversight Council demonstrates how substantive and procedural elements of administrative law can yield more significant effects on financial regulation than either element alone. The case again involved a challenge to a systemically important designation, this time by a firm so designated: Metlife. 98 Metlife’s petition alleged a host of complaints, but the most significant issue that Metlife raised was an alleged failure by FSOC to fully consider the impacts on Metlife of this particular designation and thus the need for FSOC to design its procedures to incorporate more vigorous due process protections. 99

The court found for Metlife on these grounds and rescinded its designation as a systemically important financial institution. 100 Crucial to its conclusion was its understanding that full CBA applied in this case. The Metlife court read two recent Supreme Court opinions, Michigan v. EPA 101 and Whitman v. American Trucking Ass’ns , 102 as creating a strong presumption that CBAs are applicable in regulatory actions. 103 The government had pointed out the lack of a clear statutory demand for CBA in FSOC’s decisionmaking and suggested the principle that what is not explicitly included in a statute is left to agency discretion to adopt or not adopt as it sees fit. 104 By contrast, the court saw the statutory silence in entirely different terms: the fact that CBA wasn’t explicitly prohibited by statute suggested its inclusion, given what the court read as the crucial background assumption of mandatory CBA. 105 On this view, FSOC “intentionally refused to consider the cost of regulation,” violating “a consideration that is essential to reasoned rulemaking,” and thus the designation could not stand. 106

In one sense, Metlife represents yet another articulation of the expansive use of CBA in the financial regulatory realm, in a manner largely similar to that of Business Roundtable . Yet Metlife ’s internal logic and normative implications offer a more expansive vision of the applicability of administrative doctrines than Business Roundtable itself suggested. The court in Business Roundtable saw the mandate for expansive CBA in that case as derived from the specific context of the SEC’s decisionmaking: the SEC not only had to conduct CBA, but it also had to do so to a maximum degree of effectiveness. 107 By contrast, the Metlife court read the CBA requirement as a general background rule of law, not one derived from specific context. 108 If any circumstance would seem to justify a departure from a CBA requirement, this case’s decisionmaking backdrop of relatively high epistemic uncertainty, substantial technical considerations, and convoluted consequence would seem to qualify. Indeed, such grounds have often previously justified financial regulation’s departure from general administrative law norms. 109 That the Metlife court, by contrast, saw itself as capable of assessing the metacosts and metabenefits of a CBA speaks to a more engaged judicial role.

Beyond its specific implications for the future of CBA in financial regulation, Metlife also matters for the idea of administrative procedural choice in financial regulation. Financial regulatory agencies have typically focused relatively little on issues of transparency and decisionmaking regularity, which are more concerning to their administrative counterparts. 110 Indeed, some scholarship suggests that agencies’ powers to shape procedures to the challenges they face are inherent to the business of financial regulation, much more so than they are to general administrative law. 111 Further, scholars have argued that CBA in the financial regulatory realm offers metacosts exceeding its metabenefits. 112 Yet there is also a larger point on the question of who gets to choose. Historically, financial regulation has assumed that agencies would take the lead in deciding issues of design, with the courts playing a small and even subordinate role. 113 By endorsing a more vigorous review on both procedure and substance, Metlife speaks to an entirely new vision of how the field should operate.

IV. The Doctrine (?) of Financial Administration

Taken apart, Business Roundtable , Metlife , and State National Bank each lays individual markers for an expansion of the tools of general administrative law to financial regulatory action. Taken together, they suggest an overarching indication. If one case is an anecdote, two a trend, and three a doctrine, the cases offer indications on how these related areas of the law are developing, and why. Yet efforts to normalize financial regulation offer their own concerns. If financial regulation and administrative law enjoy their special relationship because of differences in their deep logic, an approach treating financial regulation as indistinguishable from any other form of regulatory law will suffer serious deficiencies. Instead, it would be more consistent with both the history and purpose of financial regulation and administrative law to neither embrace the normalization trend entirely nor reject it as a whole; rather, courts ought to insist that any engagement must be careful, discerning, and individualized to the situation at hand.

The most obvious first factor explaining the evolution of the financial regulation–administrative law relationship is the scope of financial regulation’s new powers. Indeed, both State National Bank and Metlife dealt with authorities established under the most significant alteration in financial regulatory authority since the New Deal era: Dodd-Frank. 114 Dodd-Frank has many elements, but the law is perhaps best understood as an attempt to address perceived gaps in the traditional system of financial regulation by creating a series of powers overlapping these gaps. 115 Dodd-Frank’s powers are expansive and subject to relatively few external controls. 116 Unlike its regulatory predecessors, Dodd-Frank’s powers exist with relatively low degrees of internal constraint. 117 This combination of strong new powers with an increasingly adversarial regulatory focus has caused some scholars to see the law as introducing a quintessentially administrative law-style character to the financial regulatory space. 118

At the same time, new administrative tools seem to offer a potent (if ultimately illusory) means of providing judicial oversight over an otherwise unconstrained regulatory system. Even if the result was inapposite, the Business Roundtable and Metlife courts were not capricious in their choice to focus on CBA. Experience from other areas of administrative law suggests that CBA can be highly effective in ensuring that otherwise opaque or unaccountable agencies reconcile themselves to more coherent policy outputs. 119 More broadly, the substantial doctrines of modern administrative law have done much to constrain agency policymaking discretion — so much so that anxieties about runaway bureaucracies have largely been replaced by the opposite concern about “ossified” regulators. 120 In this light, it may matter less whether particular elements like CBA are fully appropriate; what may matter more is the logic from which out-of-control agency policymaking seems to demand some method of constraint. CBA specifically — and administrative law generally — ostensibly offers that check.

Taken apart, the combination of greater need for control and enhanced tools to achieve that control go a long way to explaining why financial regulatory normalization may be happening, and why now. Taken together, they also help explain particularly questionable elements behind the trend. In Business Roundtable , for example, it may seem incongruous that a generalist court viewed itself as more capable than the specialist administrators. If one reads the case to imply some skepticism that the SEC’s administration was analytical rather than pretextual, and the court’s stronger view of CBA as a close-enough substitute for that expertise, then the decision may appear to enjoy greater justification. 121

The approach of treating financial regulation as an ordinary subject of administrative law thus derives from real concerns, but even on those terms, the merger may harm more than help. To start, it is not clear whether the doctrines of general administrative law enjoy a more rigorous intellectual foundation than the ad hoc application of usual financial regulation. Even attempts to apply specific administrative law tools offer their own unique sets of concerns; for example, the most recent high-profile application of CBA, Michigan v. EPA , may have involved significantly more complicated concerns than the Court’s analysis revealed. 122 Perhaps some individual error is a reasonable tradeoff for systemic gains, but it is not clear how quickly the costs become “impossibly daunting.” 123

The challenges of administrative law are not unique to financial regulation, but they are amplified to an extreme degree in this space. To start, a major critique of hard look agency policing points to the gap between agency specialist knowledge and courts’ comparative institutional limitations. 124 The highly sophisticated elements of financial regulation heighten those concerns. Likewise, strong doses of judicial review raise concerns about judges substituting their own values for those of the underlying agencies, a concern even further amplified where, as in financial regulation, the relevant risks “have a speculative character.” 125

Other elements particular to financial regulation suggest reasons for discomfort with applying usual forms of administrative law to that field without any alteration. For example, it is unclear how one key principle underlying modern financial markets — that future directions are not subject to present knowledge — can be reconciled with sophisticated quantitative analysis, given that highly monetized analyses are meant to incorporate such future values. 126 Likewise, the contingent impacts of mechanisms like the OLA fit uneasily with usual standing and ripeness doctrines and offer comparatively few options for judicial remedy. 127 It might be possible to carve out special financial regulatory exceptions from general standing rules, for example, but this approach would hardly suit the one-size-fits-all approach desired by supporters of financial regulatory normalization.

Most important, perhaps, is the degree to which the application of an off-the-rack version of administrative law contradicts key principles underlying current financial regulatory mechanics. One crucial ideal behind Dodd-Frank is an increased need for agency responsiveness, particularly in crisis. 128 Administrative law, by contrast, aims to be fundamentally deliberative, focused on the “need for checks and controls” to prevent agency overzealousness. 129 Yet if one’s object is solving the most exigent challenges, it is hard to see how any zeal would be excessive.

The full, standardized doctrines of administrative law thus prove an uneasy fit with the theory and practice of financial regulation. Yet it would be overbroad to say that courts face a choice to either conduct such an extensive judicial review that it enervates agency policymaking, or else leave agencies entirely unchecked. If financial regulatory normalization proves a difficult medicine when taken as a whole, moderate doses of its elements may offer less cause for concern and may even prove salutary to the system’s general effectiveness.

To start, the administrative law tools for policing the boundaries of agency jurisdiction offer significant advantages in the financial regulatory realm. In other administrative areas, courts have historically acted to ensure agencies stand within defined limits. 130 By contrast, financial regulatory agency powers are notoriously ill defined, and the complexity of the newest set of authorities only exacerbates that issue. 131 The boundary-setting tools of general administrative law may thus be worth importing wholesale into the financial regulatory space. In practice, those tools would imply a modest but effectual role for the courts in policing agency jurisdiction, emphasizing a livable settlement between agencies and regulated parties. 132 Jurisdictional determinations also stand within the realm of court expertise and raise few concerns about the timing or extensiveness of that engagement. 133

At the same time, anxieties about the form of agency policymaking could be addressed through a similarly focused inquiry into the structures of internal agency decisionmaking. General administrative law recognizes that effective divisions of power within agencies offer advantages such as more accurate determinations, protections against biased processes, and greater likelihood of protecting individual rights. 134 These concerns are no less trenchant in financial regulation, as demonstrated by a recent D.C. Circuit decision striking down the CFPB’s single-director structure. In PHH Corp. v. CFPB , 135 the court applied a number of examples from general administrative law to find that the Bureau “departs from settled historical practice” and “threatens individual liberty far more than a multi-member independent agency does.” 136 Yet PHH also suggests that courts may effectively tailor approaches to particular regulatory circumstances: in this case, for example, the court relatively intensively engaged with the organic Dodd-Frank scheme and intended CFPB function to find a remedy of eliminating the Director’s for-cause removal requirement, rather than closing the Bureau altogether. 137

By contrast, effective scrutiny of the substance of financial regulatory policymaking likely falls between the strongly substantive inquiry of Business Roundtable and the hands-off approach of State National Bank ; the former limits any exercise of agency discretion, while the latter fails to conceptualize elements making financial regulation unique. Rather than inquire into the adequacy of the substance or procedure at issue, a court could instead ask whether the procedures emerged through a rational process. Specifically, a court could inquire whether an agency enjoyed sufficient reason for choosing the procedure that it did. 138 To the extent that this is (or should be) the state of play in broader administrative law, the applications to the financial regulatory field would seem to prove even more compelling. After all, much of the pushback to Business Roundtable pointed out that more comprehensive reviews could discourage otherwise valid agency action. 139 Yet high-level procedural rationality review would also allow means of policing agency misconduct: if it is true, for example, that the SEC in Business Roundtable intentionally chose a relatively low level of CBA to avoid the conclusions that a more vigorous analysis would have offered, then that procedural choice would lack rational justification, and a court could (and should) exercise a more intensive and skeptical review. 140 By contrast, a CBA chosen in good faith but poorly executed would not necessarily violate procedural-rationality review’s requirements — allowing courts to avoid rewarding litigants for “waging in a judicial forum a specific policy battle which they ultimately lost in the agency.” 141

Taken together, these three approaches offer a relatively consistent, tailored approach, bringing the most effective parts of administrative law into financial regulation. This proposal rests on the idea — common in modern administrative law — that those best positioned to evaluate the substance of agency action are those closest to the scene. 142 On this vision, agencies are prevented from overreach through jurisdictional policing and from underreach by strong internal checks reducing any points of particular pressure. These two sets of policing tactics orient agencies toward the political process, while a review of the rationality of an agency’s procedural choice addresses at least some concerns about agency capture or somnolence.

In practice, this system implying vigorous judicial review of the borders of agency policymaking and relative deference at the center might seem to offer relatively little difference for the run-of-the-mill circumstances. Take, for example, some challenge to a new set of bank capital standards. Under a traditional view of financial regulatory exceptionalism, such decisions might enjoy substantial deference from the courts — perhaps complete deference if adopted through the mechanisms of global agreement. In contrast, if understood as an ordinary exercise of administrative law, such a decision would face a more restrictive set of constraints — such as concerns about substantive arbitrariness, delegation, or rationality — which would potentially impose greater hurdles. The limited version of administratively normalized financial regulation would attempt to thread the two needles: if promulgated by an agency with proper jurisdiction and sufficient internal checks, and so long as sufficient reasons for the decision existed, such promulgations would be presumptively valid. For those objecting to the content of the regulation, their remedies would be through intellectual or political means — not through the courts.

If marginally more efficient for the average case, the edge problems offer perhaps the strongest arguments for such tailored normalization of administrative law. Procedural-rationality review would likely lead a case like State National Bank to emerge the same way, albeit on substantially different grounds. For the court there, the usual administrative law principles of standing and ripeness enjoyed priority over the existence of concerns specific to financial regulation. 143 A more limited approach would, by contrast, simply refuse to engage in such a balancing act, so long as the agency made a reasoned choice. Meanwhile, the process of tailored review would suggest different outcomes for Metlife and Business Roundtable , unless one views FSOC as so unconstrained that it violatedconstitutional norms. In those cases, however, the decisions would speak to the substantive concerns at issue, rather than through second-order approaches.

This is not to say that this approach would be without demerits — even administrative agencies suffer inconsistent structures, and the line between review of arbitrariness in choice and arbitrariness in substance may be blurry. 144 Yet its greatest strength would be to reconcile the major principles of administrative law and financial regulation. If administrative law’s adherence is to an ex ante rationalized decisionmaking system, then such an approach would offer those clear procedural precommittments. If financial regulation, by contrast, rests on the ideas of flexibility, responsiveness, and choice, then such an approach would offer that power, within the defined box.

Conclusion: A New Way Forward

Financial regulation and administrative law are thus related, but ultimately distinct, fields. Comparing the two shows areas of overlap but also areas of robust and deservedly continued differences. While the two enjoy similarities on a superficial level, the logical commitments underpinning each field yield significant dissimilarities. As demonstrated in practice, the wooden application of administrative law doctrines in the setting of nuanced financial regulatory actions risks harming both domains. That the fields are and should be engaged remains clear, but what the move toward financial regulatory normalization suggests is that such engagement, like any good suit, should be tailored.

^ See Gillian E. Metzger, Through the Looking Glass to a Shared Reflection: The Evolving Relationship Between Administrative Law and Financial Regulation , 78 Law & Contemp. Probs ., no. 3, 2015, at 129 (drawing distinctions between the fields and developing lessons shared).

^ See id . at 129 (“[F]inancial regulation is, after all, a form of administrative governance to which the general transsubstantive requirements of administrative law would naturally apply.”); see also Eric J. Pan, Understanding Financial Regulation , 2012 Utah L. Rev. 1897, 1902–07 (contextualizing financial regulation within larger principles of regulation).

^ See Michael S. Barr, Comment, Accountability and Independence in Financial Regulation: Checks and Balances, Public Engagement, and Other Innovations , 78 Law & Contemp. Probs ., no. 3, 2012, at 119, 120 (“[F]inancial regulation often raises unique problems that may not neatly align with the literature on administrative law mechanisms . . . .”).

^ See David Zaring, Administration by Treasury , 95 Minn. L. Rev. 187, 199–203 (2010).

^ See, e.g. , Metzger, supra note 1, at 142–44 (discussing differences on the role of the markets).

^ Compare David Zaring, Rule by Reasonableness , 63 Admin. L. Rev. 525, 543–49 (2011) (seeing financial regulation as cognizable in administrative terms), with Kristin E. Hickman, Coloring Outside the Lines: Examining Treasury’s (Lack of) Compliance with Administrative Procedure Act Rulemaking Requirements , 82 Notre Dame L. Rev. 1727 (2007) (viewing a state of curious exceptionalism).

^ Cf . Jacob E. Gersen, Recent Development, Administrative Law Goes to Wall Street: The New Administrative Process , 65 Admin. L. Rev. 689 (2013) (attempting to reconcile “new institutional arrangements” with “the administrative law framework into which they are to be slotted,” id . at 692).

^ See, e.g. , Thomas W. Merrill & Margaret L. Merrill, Dodd-Frank Orderly Liquidation Authority: Too Big for the Constitution? , 163 U. Pa. L. Rev. 165, 171 (2014) (analyzing the purported unconstitutionality of one key new provision).

^ See, e.g. , Robert B. Ahdieh, Reanalyzing Cost-Benefit Analysis: Toward A Framework of Function(s) and Form(s) , 88 N.Y.U. L. Rev. 1983, 2065–72 (2013).

^ See John C. Coates IV, Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and Implications , 124 Yale L.J . 882 (2015) (critiquing the intellectual foundations of strong CBA).

^ For an argument that this is the current state of administrative law, see Jacob Gersen & Adrian Vermeule, Thin Rationality Review , 114 Mich. L. Rev. 1355 (2016).

^ 647 F.3d 1144 (D.C. Cir. 2011).

^ 795 F.3d 48 (D.C. Cir. 2015); see also Recent Case, State National Bank of Big Spring v. Lew, 795 F.3d 48 (D.C. Cir. 2015) , 129 Harv. L. Rev. 835 (2016) (discussing that case).

^ C.A. No. 15-0045, 2016 WL 1391569 (D.D.C. Mar. 30, 2016).

^ Cf . Gillian E. Metzger, Foreword, Embracing Administrative Common Law , 80 Geo. Wash. L. Rev. 1293, 1298–1304 (showing the “dominance” of administrative common law over thinner statutory structures, id . at 1298).

^ See Daniel A. Farber & Anne Joseph O’Connell, The Lost World of Administrative Law , 92 Tex. L. Rev. 1137, 1152–54 (2014) (arguing that agencies are defined by the reasonableness of their procedures).

^ See Charles K. Whitehead, Reframing Financial Regulation , 90 B.U. L. Rev. 1, 3 (2010) (noting the division of “regulation of financial intermediaries into categories . . . based on the functions, products, and services they provided at the time”). Defining financial regulation itself proves tricky. Perhaps the best way to conceptualize it, then, is in the nature of the concerns that a regulation aims to forestall: to wit, crisis.

^ Cf . id . at 21–25 (discussing how to conceptualize nonbank actors with significant bank-like attributes and effects).

^ Cf . David S. Tatel, Remarks, The Administrative Process and the Rule of Environmental Law , 34 Harv. Envtl. L. Rev. 1 (2010) (“As environmental lawyers well know, admin is where the action is.” Id . at 1.).

^ Pub. L. No. 79-404, 60 Stat. 237 (1946) (codified as amended in scattered sections of 5 U.S.C.); see Metzger, supra note 1, at 133.

^ See Pan, supra note 2, at 1931–32 (noting how financial regulators “still rely quite frequently on private regulatory strategies” as compared to the tools of public regulatory law, id . at 1931); Sidney A. Shapiro, Outsourcing Government Regulation , 53 Duke L.J . 389, 408–09 (2003).

^ John F. Coverdale, Chevron ’s Reduced Domain: Judicial Review of Treasury Regulations and Revenue Rulings After Mead, 55 Admin. L. Rev. 39, 84 (2003). Professor John Coverdale argues that Chevron ’s absence owes mostly to error. Yet Chevron is more than just a multistep dance; it incorporates a worldview centered on allocation of powers. See generally Thomas W. Merrill & Kristin E. Hickman, Chevron ’s Domain , 89 Geo. L.J . 833, 836 (2001). Because financial regulation blurs so many jurisdictional boundaries, it is perhaps unsurprising that Chevron , the classic reward for such clarity, proves so absent.

^ See 5 U.S.C. § 701(a)(2) (2012) (exempting from judicial review “agency action [that] is committed to agency discretion by law”).

^ See, e.g. , William M. Landes & Richard A. Posner, The Positive Economic Theory of Tort Law , 15 Ga. L. Rev. 851 (1981).

^ See Metzger, supra note 15, at 1312–13.

^ Wong Yang Sung v. McGrath, 339 U.S. 33, 40 (1950) (“The [APA] . . . enacts a formula upon which opposing social and political forces have come to rest.”).

^ See Cass R. Sunstein, What’s Standing After Lujan ? Of Citizen Suits, “Injuries,” and Article III , 91 Mich. L. Rev. 163, 220–23 (1992).

^ See Metzger, supra note 1, at 130–31. Of course, administrative law cares about results, but its deep fear is agency overreach, not that an optimal policy may slip away.

^ See id . at 142–44.

^ Cf . Pan, supra note 2, at 1933–34 (showing structural challenges of financial regulators).

^ See Adam J. Levitin, The Politics of Financial Regulation and the Regulation of Financial Politics: A Review Essay , 127 Harv. L. Rev. 1991, 2041–49 (2014) (book review) (sketching the worry about “feckless or even rogue regulators,” id . at 2042).

^ See Robert B. Ahdieh, Notes From Across the Border: Writing Across the Administrative Law/Financial Regulation Divide , 66 J. Legal Educ . 64, 68 (2016) (pointing out how few financial regulatory commentators use administrative law frameworks like “notice and comment”).

^ Zaring, supra note 4, at 208–09.

^ See Ahdieh, supra note 32, at 71–72.

^ See, e.g. , Daniel R. Ernst, Tocqueville’s Nightmare: The Administrative State Emerges in America , 1900–1940 (2014) (showing administrative law’s long history); Alejandro Komai & Gary Richardson, A Brief History of Regulations Regarding Financial Markets in the United States: 1789 to 2009 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Research, Working Paper No. 17443, 2011), http://www.nber.org/papers/w17443 [ https://perma.cc/82UU-TDN2 ] (same for financial regulation).

^ To be sure, the idea of a single moment of creation may obscure more than it inspires. Cf . Lars Noah, Interpreting Agency Enabling Acts: Misplaced Metaphors in Administrative Law , 41 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 1463, 1466 (2000) (pointing to the “interpretive baggage” of enabling statutes).

^ Levitin, supra note 31, at 2039.

^ See, e.g. , Michael E. Parrish, The Great Depression, the New Deal, and the American Legal Order , 59 Wash. L. Rev. 723, 745–46 (1984); A.C. Pritchard & Robert B. Thompson, Securities Law and the New Deal Justices , 95 Va. L. Rev. 841, 846–49 (2009); Steven A. Ramirez, The Law and Macroeconomics of the New Deal at 70 , 62 Md. L. Rev. 515, 534–46 (2003).

^ See Joel Seligman , The Transformation of Wall Street 73–100 (3d ed. 2003).

^ See Pritchard & Thompson, supra note 39, at 890–92 (discussing N. Am. Co. v. SEC, 327 U.S. 686 (1946)); see also Seligman, supra note 40, at 127–53 (discussing the “imaginative and effective” activities, id . at 149).

^ See, e.g. , James J. Park, The Competing Paradigms of Securities Regulation , 57 Duke L.J . 625, 674 & n.198 (2007) (discussing the SEC’s broad discretion in choices of procedure).

^ See SEC v. Chenery Corp. ( Chenery II ), 332 U.S. 194, 204 (1947) (noting the SEC’s engagement with “particular facts in the case, its general experience in reorganization matters and its informed view of statutory requirements”); see also Pritchard & Thompson, supra note 39, at 902–07 (discussing Chenery II ).

^ Adrian Vermeule, Leviathan Had a Good War , Jotwell (Feb. 29, 2016), http://adlaw.jotwell.com/leviathan-had-a-good-war [ https://perma.cc/H5GX-Y7Z6 ] (viewing the APA as “in effect a treaty of peace”).

^ See Metzger, supra note 1, at 129.

^ See Charles H. Koch, Jr., James Landis: The Administrative Process , 48 Admin. L. Rev. 419, 425–28 (1996) (explaining Landis’s preference for administrative agencies over courts).

^ See id . at 421–25 (outlining Landis’s views).

^ Pritchard & Thompson, supra note 39, at 912.

^ See id . at 912–17.

^ See Ernst , supra note 36, at 129–32 (discussing Jerome Frank’s defense of the SEC).

^ See Ahdieh, supra note 32, at 66–67; see also Metzger, supra note 1, at 130–31.

^ See Koch, supra note 46, at 426 (noting Landis’s view of the superiority of the SEC process).

^ See Mark Tushnet, Lecture, Administrative Law in the 1930s: The Supreme Court’s Accommodation of Progressive Legal Theory , 60 Duke L.J . 1565, 1568–76 (2011).

^ See Lisa Schultz Bressman, Procedures as Politics in Administrative Law , 107 Colum. L. Rev. 1749, 1804–05 (2007) (seeing administrative law as “a bridge between law and politics,” id . at 1805); cf . Elena Kagan, Presidential Administration , 114 Harv. L. Rev. 2245 (2001) (arguing for political control).

^ See Zaring, supra note 4, at 209; see also Steven A. Ramirez, Depoliticizing Financial Regulation , 41 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 503, 504–05 (2000) (“[I]f Congress provides broad delegation of authority to a singular agency with a high degree of political independence, then effective regulation is likely . . . .”).

^ See Levitin, supra note 31, at 2041–49.

^ Cf . Ramirez, supra note 55, at 583–84 (pointing to advantages of “power and flexibility,” id . at 584).

^ See David Zaring, Sovereignty Mismatch and the New Administrative Law , 91 Wash. U. L. Rev. 59, 61–64 (2013).

^ See id . at 84–90.

^ See id . at 101–05.

^ Compare Levitin, supra note 31, at 2038–39 (seeing 2008 as posing “a crisis of faith in the financial regulatory system and its underlying claims to technocratic or scientific expertise,” id . at 2039), with Brett McDonnell, Don’t Panic! Defending Cowardly Interventions During and After a Financial Crisis , 116 Penn St. L. Rev. 1 (2011) (acknowledging an increasingly “complex and diverse” financial system, id . at 18).

^ See Levitin, supra note 31, at 2041–42 (discussing industry capture).

^ See David Zaring, Litigating the Financial Crisis , 100 Va. L. Rev. 1405, 1420–34 (2014) (discussing failed challenges to government actions).

^ See generally Metzger, supra note 1.

^ See, e.g. , Gersen, supra note 7 (“[F]inancial reform statutes . . . paint on a working canvass [sic] of existing administrative law.” Id . at 734.).

^ Bus. Roundtable v. SEC, 647 F.3d 1144, 1146–48 (D.C. Cir. 2011).

^ 15 U.S.C. § 78n(a) (2012).

^ Bus. Roundtable , 647 F.3d at 1147.

^ Id . at 1146.

^ Id . at 1148–49.

^ Facilitating Shareholder Director Nominations, 74 Fed. Reg. 29,024, 29,025 (proposed June 18, 2009) (to be codified in scattered parts of 17 C.F.R.) (expressing those views).

^ 5 U.S.C. § 706(2)(A) (2012).

^ Bus. Roundtable , 647 F.3d at 1149–51.

^ Id . at 1148 (quoting Chamber of Commerce v. SEC, 412 F.3d 133, 144 (D.C. Cir. 2005)).

^ See, e.g. , Richard L. Revesz, Quantifying Regulatory Benefits , 102 Calif. L. Rev. 1423, 1430 (2014).

^ See, e.g. , James D. Cox & Benjamin J.C. Baucom, The Emperor Has No Clothes: Confronting the D.C. Circuit’s Usurpation of SEC Rulemaking Authority , 90 Tex. L. Rev. 1811, 1828 (2012) (critiquing a perceived end to deference by the D.C. Circuit); Jonathan D. Guynn, Note, The Political Economy of Financial Rulemaking After Business Roundtable, 99 Va. L. Rev. 641, 664–67 (2013) (arguing that Business Roundtable presents a new, nondeferential regime).

^ See Bus. Roundtable , 647 F.3d at 1151.

^ See Coates, supra note 10.

^ See id . at 998–1003.

^ Cf . Bruce Kraus & Connor Raso, Rational Boundaries for SEC Cost-Benefit Analysis , 30 Yale J. on Reg . 289, 335–36 (2013) (“Economic analysis should therefore inform, but should not be expected or allowed to dictate, policy.” Id . at 336). But see Cass R. Sunstein, Financial Regulation and Cost-Benefit Analysis , 124 Yale L.J.F . 263, 270 (2015) (arguing CBA is possible and desirable).

^ Cass R. Sunstein, Cost-Benefit Analysis and Arbitrariness Review 3–4 (Harvard Pub. Law Working Paper No. 16-12, 2016), http://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2752068 [ https://perma.cc/Q8SV-7BTZ ] (explaining the “maximalist” view).

^ See Caroline Cecot & W. Kip Viscusi, Judicial Review of Agency Benefit-Cost Analysis , 22 Geo. Mason L. Rev. 575, 591 (2015).

^ Perhaps the strongest defense of the Business Roundtable court is a view that its objections are about pretext: concern that the SEC hadn’t taken its duties seriously at all. See Jill E. Fisch, The Long Road Back: Business Roundtable and the Future of SEC Rulemaking , 36 Seattle U. L. Rev. 695, 700–01 (2013).

^ See Coates, supra note 10, at 909–12.

^ Pub. L. No. 111-203, 124 Stat. 1376 (2010) (codified in scattered sections of the U.S. Code).

^ State Nat’l Bank of Big Spring v. Lew, 795 F.3d 48, 51–52 (D.C. Cir. 2015); see also 12 U.S.C. § 5384 (2012).

^ State Nat’l Bank , 795 F.3d at 52.

^ Id . at 55.

^ Id . at 56; see also id . (“State plaintiffs will be affected . . . only if a company in which they are invested is liquidated or reorganized by the Government, and only if the States are then treated differently from other similarly situated creditors.”).

^ Id . at 54 (citing Free Enter. Fund v. Pub. Co. Accounting Oversight Bd., 561 U.S. 477, 490 (2010)).

^ See generally Recent Case, supra note 13 (discussing State National Bank ).

^ See Coates, supra note 10, at 1002 (pointing to the “non-stationary” attributes of financial markets).

^ See Recent Case, supra note 13, at 840.

^ See Zaring, supra note 63, at 1431–34 (advocating for this approach).

^ See, e.g. , Carolyn Sissoko, Note, Is Financial Regulation Structurally Biased to Favor Deregulation? , 86 S. Cal. L. Rev. 365, 402–03 (2013).

^ See Mark J. Roe & Michael Tröge, Taxing Banks Properly: The Next Regulatory Frontier , at 11 (2016), http://web.law.columbia.edu/sites/default/files/microsites/law-economics-studies/taxingbanksproperly_feb_20_2016_v5.2.pdf [ https://perma.cc/5E5L-ZSNW ].

^ C.A. No. 15-0045, 2016 WL 1391569, at *1 (D.D.C. Mar. 30, 2016).

^ See id . at *14–15.

^ Id . at *17.

^ 135 S. Ct. 2699 (2015).

^ 531 U.S. 457 (2001).

^ Metlife , 2016 WL 1391569, at *15–16.

^ Id . at *15.

^ See id . at *15–16.

^ See Bus. Roundtable v. SEC, 647 F.3d 1144, 1148–51 (D.C. Cir. 2011) (setting out specific factors the agency should have considered in its CBA).

^ Metlife , 2016 WL 1391569, at *15–17.

^ See Steven L. Schwarcz, Regulating Financial Change: A Functional Approach , 100 Minn. L. Rev. 1441, 1463–69 (2016) (noting and critiquing the historically ad hoc approach to regulation in the financial context).

^ See Ahdieh, supra note 32, at 73–74.

^ See Zaring, supra note 6, at 544–46 (developing that sensibility).

^ See Coates, supra note 10, at 1011.

^ See Ramirez, supra note 55, at 527–28.

^ See generally Robert G. Kaiser , Act of Congress (2013) (discussing Dodd-Frank).

^ See Barr, supra note 3, at 123 (“FSOC’s authorities fill important gaps in the system and help to reduce the risk of regulatory arbitrage.”).

^ See, e.g. , Merrill & Merrill, supra note 8, at 172.

^ See Gersen, supra note 7, at 691–92 (outlining the point).

^ See Metzger, supra note 1, at 145–46 (arguing that Dodd-Frank shows how “that divide [between financial regulation and administrative law] is now collapsing”).

^ See Sunstein, supra note 82 (manuscript at 5–8) (developing the argument from a social welfare perspective).

^ See Kagan, supra note 54, at 2266–67 (discussing contemporary fears of regulatory slowdown).

^ See Fisch, supra note 84, at 700–01.

^ Lisa Heinzerling, The Power Canons , 58 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. (forthcoming 2017) (manuscript at 23–25), https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2757770 [ https://perma.cc/MXG2-K34B ]. Of course, the underlying administrative law has also undergone substantive evolutions. See, e.g. , The Supreme Court, 2014 Term — Leading Cases , 129 Harv. L. Rev. 181, 317–26 (2015).

^ Sunstein, supra note 81, at 275.

^ See Motor Vehicle Mfrs. Ass’n v. State Farm Mut. Auto. Ins. Co., 463 U.S. 29 (1983); Stephen Breyer, Judicial Review of Questions of Law and Policy , 38 Admin. L. Rev. 363, 388–94 (1986). But see Gersen & Vermeule, supra note 11 (arguing that current law shows little evidence of hard look review).

^ See Cass R. Sunstein & Adrian Vermeule, Libertarian Administrative Law , 82 U. Chi. L. Rev. 393, 450 (2015).

^ See Donald C. Langevoort, Theories, Assumptions, and Securities Regulation: Market Efficiency Revisited , 140 U. Pa. L. Rev. 851, 851 (1992).

^ See Recent Case, supra note 13, at 840–41.

^ See Barr, supra note 3, at 123.

^ See Breyer, supra note 124, at 363.

^ See Thomas W. Merrill, Step Zero After City of Arlington, 83 Fordham L. Rev. 753, 754–55 (2014) (discussing “the traditional judicial function of boundary maintenance,” id . at 755).

^ See, e.g. , Merrill & Merrill, supra note 8. To take the most visible example, a number of recent cases have involved questions about the scope of the CFPB’s authority. See CFPB v. Accrediting Council for Indep. Colls. & Sch., No. 15-1838, 2016 WL 1625084, at *2–4 (D.D.C. Apr. 21, 2016); CFPB v. Mortg. Law Grp., LLP, 157 F. Supp. 3d 813, 819–21 (W.D. Wis. 2016); CFPB v. ITT Educ. Servs., Inc., No. 1:14-CV-00292, 2015 WL 1013508, at *21–24 (S.D. Ind. Mar. 6, 2015).

^ See Merrill, supra note 130, at 757.

^ See Jacob E. Gersen, Overlapping and Underlapping Jurisdiction in Administrative Law , 2006 Sup. Ct. Rev. 201, 216–19. But see The Supreme Court, 2015 Term — Leading Cases , 130 Harv. L. Rev. 307, 447–56 (2016).

^ See Jon D. Michaels, An Enduring, Evolving Separation of Powers , 115 Colum. L. Rev. 515, 530–31 (2015).

^ 839 F.3d 1 (D.C. Cir. 2016).

^ Id . at 8; id . at 34.

^ Id . at 37–39.

^ See Adrian Vermeule, Essay, Deference and Due Process , 129 Harv. L. Rev. 1890, 1916 (2016).

^ See Revesz, supra note 76, at 1430.

^ Cf . Balt. Gas & Elec. Co. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc., 462 U.S. 87, 97–98 (1983) (“The role of the courts is simply to ensure that the agency has adequately considered and disclosed the . . . impact of its actions . . . .”).

^ Chevron U.S.A. Inc. v. Nat. Res. Def. Council, Inc., 467 U.S. 837, 864 (1984).

^ Cf . Vermeule, supra note 138, at 1916.

^ See State Nat’l Bank of Big Spring v. Lew, 795 F.3d 48, 56 (D.C. Cir. 2015).

^ Cf . Ronald M. Levin, Administrative Procedure and Judicial Restraint , 129 Harv. L. Rev. F . 338 (2016).

  • Administrative Law
  • Financial Regulation

February 10, 2017

More from this Issue

Restoring legitimacy: the grand jury as the prosecutor’s administrative agency, the rise of purposivism and the fall of chevron : major statutory cases in the supreme court, in re al-nashiri.

D.C. Circuit Abstains from Adjudicating Habeas Petition of Guantanamo Detainee Tried by Military Commission.

Discover the latest MyICAEW app for ACA students and members, available to download now. Find out more

  • Benefits of membership

Gain access to world-leading information resources, guidance and local networks.

  • Visit Benefits of membership

Becoming a member

98% of the best global brands rely on ICAEW Chartered Accountants.

  • Visit Becoming a member
  • Pay fees and subscriptions

Your membership subscription enables ICAEW to provide support to members.

Fees and subscriptions

Member rewards.

Take advantage of the range of value added or discounted member benefits.

  • Member rewards – More from your membership
  • Technical and ethics support
  • Support throughout your career

Information and resources for every stage of your career.

Member Insights Survey

Let us know about the issues affecting you, your business and your clients.

  • Complete the survey

From software start-ups to high-flying airlines and high street banks, 98% of the best global brands rely on ICAEW Chartered Accountants. A career as an ICAEW Chartered Accountant means the opportunity to work in any organisation, in any sector, whatever your ambitions.

Everything you need to know about ICAEW annual membership fees, community and faculty subscriptions, eligibility for reduced rates and details of how you can pay.

Membership administration

Welcome to the ICAEW members area: your portal to members'-only content, offers, discounts, regulations and membership information.

  • Continuing Professional Development (CPD)

Continuing Professional Development (CPD) is an integral part of being a successful ICAEW Chartered Accountant.

The ICAEW Chartered Accountant qualification, the ACA, is one of the most advanced learning and professional development programmes available. It is valued around the world in business, practice and the public sector.

3 people huddled at desk

ACA for employers

Train the next generation of chartered accountants in your business or organisation. Discover how your organisation can attract, train and retain the best accountancy talent, how to become authorised to offer ACA training and the support and guidance on offer if you are already providing training.

Digital learning materials via BibliU

All ACA, ICAEW CFAB and Level 4 apprenticeship learning materials are now digital only. Read our guide on how to access your learning materials on the ICAEW Bookshelf using the BibliU app or through your browser.

  • Find out more

Take a look at ICAEW training films

Focusing on professional scepticism, ethics and everyday business challenges, our training films are used by firms and companies around the world to support their in-house training and business development teams.

Attract and retain the next generation of accounting and finance professionals with our world-leading accountancy qualifications. Become authorised to offer ACA training and help your business stay ahead.

CPD guidance and help

Continuing Professional Development (CPD) is an integral part of being a successful ICAEW Chartered Accountant. Find support on ICAEW's CPD requirements and access resources to help your professional development.

ICAEW flagship events

ICAEW boasts an extensive portfolio of industry-leading conferences. These flagship events offer the opportunity to hear from and interact with all the key players in the industry. Find out what's coming up.

Leadership Development Programmes

ICAEW Academy’s in-depth leadership development programmes take a holistic approach to combine insightful mentoring or coaching, to exclusive events, peer learning groups and workshops. Catering for those significant transitions in your career, these leadership development programmes are instrumental to achieving your ambitions or fulfilling your succession planning goals.

Specialist Finance Qualifications & Programmes

Whatever future path you choose, ICAEW will support the development and acceleration of your career at each stage to enhance your career.

 Young people

Why a career in chartered accountancy?

If you think chartered accountants spend their lives confined to their desks, then think again. They are sitting on the boards of multinational companies, testifying in court and advising governments, as well as supporting charities and businesses from every industry all over the world.

  • Why chartered accountancy?

 Telescope

Search for qualified ACA jobs

Matching highly skilled ICAEW members with attractive organisations seeking talented accountancy and finance professionals.

Volunteering roles

Helping skilled and in-demand chartered accountants give back and strengthen not-for-profit sector with currently over 2,300 organisations posting a variety of volunteering roles with ICAEW.

  • Search for volunteer roles
  • Get ahead by volunteering

Advertise with ICAEW

From as little as £495, access to a pool of highly qualified and ambitious ACA qualified members with searchable CVs.

Early careers and training

Start your ACA training with ICAEW. Find out why a career in chartered accountancy could be for you and how to become a chartered accountant.

Qualified ACA careers

Find Accountancy and Finance Jobs

Voluntary roles

Find Voluntary roles

While you pursue the most interesting and rewarding opportunities at every stage of your career, we’re here to offer you support whatever stage you are or wherever you are in the world and in whichever sector you have chosen to work.

ACA students

"how to guides" for aca students.

  • ACA student guide
  • How to book an exam
  • How to apply for credit for prior learning (CPL)

Exam resources

Here are some resources you will find useful while you study for the ACA qualification.

  • Certificate Level
  • Professional Level
  • Advanced Level

Digital learning materials

All ACA learning materials are now digital only. Read our guide on how to access your learning materials on the ICAEW Bookshelf via the BibliU app, or through your browser.

  • Read the guide

My online training file

Once you are registered as an ACA student, you'll be able to access your training file to log your progress throughout ACA training.

  • Access your training file
  • Student Insights

Fresh insights, innovative ideas and an inside look at the lives and careers of our ICAEW students and members.

  • Read the latest articles

System status checks

Getting started.

Welcome to ICAEW! We have pulled together a selection of resources to help you get started with your ACA training, including our popular 'How To' series, which offers step-by-step guidance on everything from registering as an ACA student and applying for CPL, to using your online training file.

Credit for prior learning (CPL)

Credit for prior learning or CPL is our term for exemptions. High quality learning and assessment in other relevant qualifications is appropriately recognised by the award of CPL.

Apply for exams

What you need to know in order to apply for the ACA exams.

The ACA qualification has 15 modules over three levels. They are designed to complement the practical experience you will be gaining in the workplace. They will also enable you to gain in-depth knowledge across a broad range of topics in accountancy, finance and business. Here are some useful resources while you study.

  • Exam results

You will receive your results for all Certificate Level exams, the day after you take the exam and usually five weeks after a Professional and Advanced Level exam session has taken place. Access your latest and archived exam results here.

Training agreement

Putting your theory work into practice is essential to complete your ACA training.

Student support and benefits

We are here to support you throughout your ACA journey. We have a range of resources and services on offer for you to unwrap, from exam resources, to student events and discount cards. Make sure you take advantage of the wealth of exclusive benefits available to you, all year round.

  • Applying for membership

The ACA will open doors to limitless opportunities in all areas of accountancy, business and finance anywhere in the world. ICAEW Chartered Accountants work at the highest levels as finance directors, CEOs and partners of some of the world’s largest organisations.

ACA training FAQs

Do you have a question about the ACA training? Then look no further. Here, you can find answers to frequently asked questions relating to the ACA qualification and training. Find out more about each of the integrated components of the ACA, as well as more information on the syllabus, your training agreement, ICAEW’s rules and regulations and much more.

  • Anti-money laundering

Guidance and resources to help members comply with their legal and professional responsibilities around AML.

Technical releases

ICAEW Technical Releases are a source of good practice guidance on technical and practice issues relevant to ICAEW Chartered Accountants and other finance professionals.

  • ICAEW Technical Releases
  • Thought leadership

ICAEW's Thought Leadership reports provide clarity and insight on the current and future challenges to the accountancy profession. Our charitable trusts also provide funding for academic research into accountancy.

  • Academic research funding

Technical Advisory Services helpsheets

Practical, technical and ethical guidance highlighting the most important issues for members, whether in practice or in business.

  • ICAEW Technical Advisory Services helpsheets

Bloomsbury – free for eligible firms

In partnership with Bloomsbury Professional, ICAEW have provided eligible firms with free access to Bloomsbury’s comprehensive online library of around 80 titles from leading tax and accounting subject matter experts.

  • Bloomsbury Accounting and Tax Service

Country resources

Our resources by country provide access to intelligence on over 170 countries and territories including economic forecasts, guides to doing business and information on the tax climate in each jurisdiction.

Industries and sectors

Thought leadership, technical resources and professional guidance to support the professional development of members working in specific industries and sectors.

Audit and Assurance

The audit, assurance and internal audit area has information and guidance on technical and practical matters in relation to these three areas of practice. There are links to events, publications, technical help and audit representations.

The most up-to-date thought leadership, insights, technical resources and professional guidance to support ICAEW members working in and with industry with their professional development.

  • Corporate Finance

Companies, advisers and investors making decisions about creating, developing and acquiring businesses – and the wide range of advisory careers that require this specialist professional expertise.

  • Corporate governance

Corporate governance is the system by which companies are directed and controlled. Find out more about corporate governance principles, codes and reports, Board subcommittees, roles and responsibilities and shareholder relations. Corporate governance involves balancing the interests of a company’s many stakeholders, such as shareholders, employees, management, customers, suppliers, financiers and the community. Getting governance right is essential to build public trust in companies.

Corporate reporting

View a range of practical resources on UK GAAP, IFRS, UK regulation for company accounts and non-financial reporting. Plus find out more about the ICAEW Corporate Reporting Faculty.

Expert analysis on the latest national and international economic issues and trends, and interviews with prominent voices across the finance industry, alongside data on the state of the economy.

  • Financial Services

View articles and resources on the financial services sector.

  • Practice resources

For ICAEW's members in practice, this area brings together the most up-to-date thought leadership, technical resources and professional guidance to help you in your professional life.

Public Sector

Many ICAEW members work in or with the public sector to deliver public priorities and strong public finances. ICAEW acts in the public interest to support strong financial leadership and better financial management across the public sector – featuring transparency, accountability, governance and ethics – to ensure that public money is spent wisely and that public finances are sustainable.

Sustainability and climate change

Sustainability describes a world that does not live by eating into its capital, whether natural, economic or social. Members in practice, in business and private individuals all have a role to play if sustainability goals are to be met. The work being undertaken by ICAEW in this area is to change behaviour to drive sustainable outcomes.

The Tax area has information and guidance on technical and practical tax matters. There are links to events, the latest tax news and the Tax Faculty’s publications, including helpsheets, webinars and Tax representations.

Keep up-to-date with tech issues and developments, including artificial intelligence (AI), blockchain, big data, and cyber security.

Trust & Ethics

Guidance and resources on key issues, including economic crime, business law, better regulation and ethics. Read through ICAEW’s Code of Ethics and supporting information.

Communities

Polaroids on pinboard

ICAEW Communities

Information, guidance and networking opportunities on industry sectors, professional specialisms and at various stages throughout your career. Free for ICAEW members and students.

  • Discover a new community

Faculties

ICAEW Faculties

The accountancy profession is facing change and uncertainty. The ICAEW Faculties can help by providing you with timely and relevant support.

  • Choose to join any of the faculties

UK groups and societies

We have teams on the ground in: East of England, the Midlands, London and South East, Northern, South West, Yorkshire and Humberside, Wales and Scotland.

  • Access your UK region
  • Worldwide support and services

Support and services we offer our members in Africa, America, Canada, the Caribbean, Europe, Greater China, the Middle East, Oceania and South East Asia.

  • Discover our services

ICAEW Faculties are 'centres of technical excellence', strongly committed to enhancing your professional development and helping you to meet your CPD requirements every year. They offer exclusive content, events and webinars, customised for your sector - which you should be able to easily record, when the time comes for the completion of your CPD declaration. Our offering isn't exclusive to Institute members. As a faculty member, the same resources are available to you to ensure you stay ahead of the competition.

Communities by industry / sector

Communities by life stage and workplace, communities by professional specialism, local groups and societies.

We aim to support you wherever in the world you work. Our regional offices and network of volunteers run events and provide access to local accounting updates in major finance centres around the globe.

  • Ukraine crisis: central resource hub

Learn about the actions that ICAEW members are taking to ensure that their clients comply with sanctions imposed by different countries and jurisdictions, and read about the support available from ICAEW.

Insights pulls together the best opinion, analysis, interviews, videos and podcasts on the key issues affecting accountancy and business.

  • See the latest insights
  • Making COP count

This series looks at the role the accountancy profession can play in addressing the climate crisis and building a sustainable economy.

  • Read more on COP28

Professional development and skills

With new requirements on ICAEW members for continuing professional development, we bring together resources to support you through the changes and look at the skills accountants need for the future.

  • Visit the hub

When Chartered Accountants Save The World

Find out how chartered accountants are helping to tackle some of the most urgent social challenges within the UN Sustainable Development Goals, and explore how the profession could do even more.

  • Read our major series

Insights specials

A listing of one-off Insights specials that focus on a particular subject, interviewing the key people, identifying developing trends and examining the underlying issues.

Top podcasts

Insights by topic.

Regulation graphic

ICAEW Regulation

Regulation graphic

  • Regulatory News

View the latest regulatory updates and guidance and subscribe to our monthly newsletter, Regulatory & Conduct News.

  • Regulatory Consultations

Strengthening trust in the profession

Our role as a world-leading improvement regulator is to strengthen trust and protect the public. We do this by enabling, evaluating and enforcing the highest standards in the profession. 

Regulatory applications

Find out how you can become authorised by ICAEW as a regulated firm. 

ICAEW codes and regulations

Professional conduct and complaints, statutory regulated services overseen by icaew, regulations for icaew practice members and firms, additional guidance and support, popular search results.

  • Training File
  • Practice Exam Software
  • Ethics Cpd Course
  • Routes to the ACA
  • ACA students membership application
  • Join as a member of another body
  • How much are membership fees?
  • How to pay your fees
  • Receipts and invoices
  • What if my circumstances have changed?
  • Difficulties in making changes to your membership
  • Faculty and community subscription fees
  • Updating your details
  • Complete annual return
  • Promoting myself as an ICAEW member
  • Verification of ICAEW membership
  • Become a life member
  • Become a fellow
  • Request a new certificate
  • Report the death of a member
  • Membership regulations
  • New members
  • Career progression
  • Career Breakers
  • Volunteering at schools and universities
  • ICAEW Member App
  • Working internationally
  • Self employment
  • Support Members Scheme
  • CPD is changing
  • CPD learning resources
  • Your guide to CPD
  • Online CPD record
  • How to become a chartered accountant
  • Register as a student
  • Train as a member of another body
  • More about the ACA and chartered accountancy
  • How ACA training works
  • Become a training employer
  • Access the training file
  • Why choose the ACA
  • Training routes
  • Employer support hub
  • Get in touch
  • Apprenticeships with ICAEW
  • A-Z of CPD courses by topic
  • ICAEW Business and Finance Professional (BFP)
  • ICAEW Annual Conference 2024
  • Audit & Assurance Conference 2024
  • Restructuring & Insolvency Conference
  • Virtual CPD Conference
  • Virtual Healthcare Conference 2024
  • All our flagship events
  • Financial Talent Executive Network (F-TEN®)
  • Developing Leadership in Practice (DLiP™)
  • Network of Finance Leaders (NFL)
  • Women in Leadership (WiL)
  • Mentoring and coaching
  • Partners in Learning
  • Board Director's Programme e-learning
  • Corporate Finance Qualification
  • Diploma in Charity Accounting
  • ICAEW Certificate in Insolvency
  • ICAEW Data Analytics Certificate
  • Financial Modeling Institute’s Advanced Financial Modeler Accreditation
  • ICAEW Sustainability Certificate for Finance Professionals
  • ICAEW Finance in a Digital World Programme
  • All specialist qualifications
  • Team training
  • Start your training
  • Improve your employability
  • Search employers
  • Find a role
  • Role alerts
  • Organisations
  • Practice support – 11 ways ICAEW and CABA can help you
  • News and advice
  • ICAEW Volunteering Hub
  • Support in becoming a chartered accountant
  • Vacancies at ICAEW
  • ICAEW boards and committees
  • Exam system status
  • ICAEW systems: status update
  • Changes to our qualifications
  • How-to guides for ACA students
  • Apply for credits - Academic qualification
  • Apply for credits - Professional qualification
  • Credit for prior learning (CPL)/exemptions FAQs
  • Applications for Professional and Advanced Level exams
  • Applications for Certificate Level exams
  • Tuition providers
  • Latest exam results
  • Archived exam results
  • Getting your results
  • Marks feedback service
  • Exam admin check
  • Training agreement: overview
  • Professional development
  • Ethics and professional scepticism
  • Practical work experience
  • Access your online training file
  • How training works in your country
  • Student rewards
  • TOTUM PRO Card
  • Student events and volunteering
  • Xero cloud accounting certifications
  • Student support
  • Join a community
  • Wellbeing support from caba
  • Student mentoring programme
  • Student conduct and behaviour
  • Code of ethics
  • Fit and proper
  • Level 4 Accounting Technician Apprenticeship
  • Level 7 Accountancy Professional Apprenticeship
  • AAT-ACA Fast Track FAQs
  • ACA rules and regulations FAQs
  • ACA syllabus FAQs
  • ACA training agreement FAQs
  • Audit experience and the Audit Qualification FAQs
  • Independent student FAQs
  • Practical work experience FAQs
  • Professional development FAQs
  • Six-monthly reviews FAQs
  • Ethics and professional scepticism FAQs
  • Greater China
  • Latin America
  • Middle East
  • North America
  • Australasia
  • Russia and Eurasia
  • South East Asia
  • Charity Community
  • Construction & Real Estate
  • Energy & Natural Resources Community
  • Farming & Rural Business Community
  • Forensic & Expert Witness
  • Global Trade Community
  • Healthcare Community
  • Internal Audit Community
  • Manufacturing Community
  • Media & Leisure
  • Portfolio Careers Community
  • Small and Micro Business Community
  • Small Practitioners Community
  • Travel, Tourism & Hospitality Community
  • Valuation Community
  • Audit and corporate governance reform
  • Audit & Assurance Faculty
  • Professional judgement
  • Regulation and working in audit
  • Internal audit resource centre
  • ICAEW acting on audit quality
  • Everything business
  • Latest Business news from Insights
  • Strategy, risk and innovation
  • Business performance management
  • Financial management
  • Finance transformation
  • Economy and business environment
  • Leadership, personal development and HR
  • Webinars and publications
  • Business restructuring
  • The Business Finance Guide
  • Capital markets and investment
  • Corporate finance careers
  • Corporate Finance Faculty
  • Debt advisory and growth finance
  • Mergers and acquisitions
  • Private equity
  • Start-ups, scale-ups and venture capital
  • Transaction services
  • Board committees and board effectiveness
  • Corporate governance codes and reports
  • Corporate Governance Community
  • Principles of corporate governance
  • Roles, duties and responsibilities of Board members
  • Stewardship and stakeholder relations
  • Corporate Governance thought leadership
  • Corporate reporting resources
  • Small and micro entity reporting
  • UK Regulation for Company Accounts
  • Non-financial reporting
  • Improving Corporate Reporting
  • Economy home
  • ICAEW Business Confidence Monitor
  • ICAEW Manifesto 2024
  • Energy crisis
  • Levelling up: rebalancing the UK’s economy
  • Resilience and Renewal: Building an economy fit for the future
  • Social mobility and inclusion
  • Autumn Statement 2023
  • Investment management
  • Inspiring confidence
  • Setting up in practice
  • Running your practice
  • Supporting your clients
  • Practice technology
  • TAS helpsheets
  • Support for business advisers
  • Join ICAEW BAS
  • Public Sector hub
  • Public Sector Audit and Assurance
  • Public Sector Finances
  • Public Sector Financial Management
  • Public Sector Financial Reporting
  • Public Sector Learning & Development
  • Public Sector Community
  • Latest public sector articles from Insights
  • Climate hub
  • Sustainable Development Goals
  • Accountability
  • Modern slavery
  • Resources collection
  • Sustainability Committee
  • Sustainability & Climate Change community
  • Sustainability and climate change home
  • Tax Faculty
  • Budgets and legislation
  • Business tax
  • Devolved taxes
  • Employment taxes
  • International taxes
  • Making Tax Digital
  • Personal tax
  • Property tax
  • Stamp duty land tax
  • Tax administration
  • Tax compliance and investigation
  • UK tax rates, allowances and reliefs
  • Artificial intelligence
  • Blockchain and cryptoassets
  • Cyber security
  • Data Analytics Community
  • Digital skills
  • Excel community
  • Finance in a Digital World
  • IT management
  • Technology and the profession
  • Trust & Ethics home
  • Better regulation
  • Business Law
  • UK company law
  • Data protection and privacy
  • Economic crime
  • Help with ethical problems
  • ICAEW Code of Ethics
  • ICAEW Trust and Ethics team.....
  • Solicitors Community
  • Forensic & Expert Witness Community
  • Latest articles on business law, trust and ethics
  • Audit and Assurance Faculty
  • Corporate Reporting Faculty
  • Financial Services Faculty
  • Academia & Education Community
  • Construction & Real Estate Community
  • Entertainment, Sport & Media Community
  • Retail Community
  • Career Breakers Community
  • Black Members Community
  • Diversity & Inclusion Community
  • Women in Finance Community
  • Personal Financial Planning Community
  • Restructuring & Insolvency Community
  • Sustainability and Climate Change Community
  • London and East
  • South Wales
  • Yorkshire and Humberside
  • European public policy activities
  • ICAEW Middle East
  • Latest news
  • Access to finance special
  • Attractiveness of the profession
  • Audit and Fraud
  • Audit and technology
  • Adopting non-financial reporting standards
  • Cost of doing business
  • Mental health and wellbeing
  • Pensions and Personal Finance
  • Public sector financial and non-financial reporting
  • More specials ...
  • The economics of biodiversity
  • How chartered accountants can help to safeguard trust in society
  • Video: The financial controller who stole £20,000 from her company
  • It’s time for chartered accountants to save the world
  • Video: The CFO who tried to trick the market
  • Video: Could invoice fraud affect your business?
  • Company size thresholds and CGT on residences
  • Lessons in leadership from ICAEW's CEO
  • So you want to be a leader?
  • A busy new tax year, plus progress on the Economic Crime Act
  • Does Britain have a farming problem?
  • Budget 2024: does it change anything?
  • Will accountants save the world? With ICAEW CEO Michael Izza
  • Crunch time: VAT (or not) on poppadoms
  • Where next for audit and governance reform?
  • A taxing year ahead?
  • What can we expect from 2024?
  • More podcasts...
  • Top charts of the week
  • EU and international trade
  • CEO and President's insights
  • Diversity and Inclusion
  • Sponsored content
  • Insights index
  • Charter and Bye-laws
  • Archive of complaints, disciplinary and fitness processes, statutory regulations and ICAEW regulations
  • Qualifications regulations
  • Training and education regulations
  • How to make a complaint
  • Guidance on your duty to report misconduct
  • Public hearings
  • What to do if you receive a complaint against you
  • Anti-money laundering supervision
  • Working in the regulated area of audit
  • Local public audit in England
  • Probate services
  • Designated Professional Body (Investment Business) licence
  • Consumer credit
  • Quality Assurance monitoring: view from the firms
  • The ICAEW Practice Assurance scheme
  • Licensed Practice scheme
  • Professional Indemnity Insurance (PII)
  • Clients' Money Regulations
  • Taxation (PCRT) Regulations
  • ICAEW training films
  • Helpsheets and guidance by topic
  • ICAEW's regulatory expertise and history
  • Regulatory and Conduct news May 2024

Disciplinary case study: insolvency practitioner fees

Author: Professional Standards Department

Published: 13 May 2024

SHARE THIS ARTICLE

Reasonable remuneration.

Justine Carruthers, Head of Insolvency Investigations, ICAEW Conduct Department summarises the details of the case.

The case was referred for investigation by the Conduct Department following a routine quality assurance review. The issue related to the appropriateness of the level of fees charged by one IP in two similar liquidations.

Due to the nature of the businesses involved, there had been significant enquiries from a government body requesting employee information. The IP had determined that it was appropriate and necessary to deal with each of those enquiries themselves which led to significant time costs, compounded by the fact that the employee information was held by a separate third party,. The IP effectively acted as an information conduit between the third party and the government body meaning, crucially, that dealing with the enquiries personally could have no benefit to creditors.

Following investigation, and in line with the relevant prima facie test at the time, the Conduct Committee found there to be evidence that, amongst other matters, the IP’s remuneration had been unreasonable and/or excessive for the time charged in dealing with those enquiries. The Conduct Committee determined that the matter should be referred to the Tribunals Committee for sanction, with the matter ultimately being concluded by settlement.

Basis of unreasonableness

The primary factor in support of the complaint that the remuneration was unreasonable, was that the IP undertook the majority of responses to the government body themselves, which were charged to the estate at the partner’s usual hourly rate.

We contended that it was neither necessary, nor appropriate, that the IP dealt with those enquiries themselves as it did not need to be done by a senior member of staff. Accordingly, time was charged to the estates that was either not required or excessive, and would not benefit creditors.

The IP had a valid fee resolution (on a time cost basis) for each of the liquidations, and there was no concern in that regard.

Narrative recording

In both cases, the complaint was aggravated by a lack of narrative in the time records. Time was charged almost exclusively in hourly blocks, rather than in 6-minute increments, and the IP used vague and repetitive narratives. It was therefore impossible to determine exactly what work was being undertaken at any given time.

The IP accepted that fees for this area of work had been disproportionately weighted towards partner time and that some of the time costs incurred, and recovered, were unreasonable and excessive.

The IP received a severe reprimand, a financial penalty of £20,000 and was required to pay costs of £25,365. The IP also agreed to repay £100,000 of their remuneration back into the insolvent estates, which necessitated restoring the companies.

Key takeaways

An IP is required to justify the level of time costs incurred, and to evidence that time with an appropriate narrative. It is not sufficient to merely have a valid fee resolution. An IP must maintain sufficient records to demonstrate the actions taken by the IP and to allow an informed third party to reach a view on the appropriateness of those actions.

An IP is obliged to consider the overall reasonableness of their work and the impact of the costs incurred on the insolvent estate. A key part of that is the appropriateness of work undertaken by different grades of staff, and if junior staff members are not available, then senior staff should consider reducing their charge out rates accordingly for those specific tasks.

Fundamentally, while IPs should charge for time that has been properly incurred, charging the highest possible rate (ie, a partner rate) for work that could be done by lower grade staff, and then seeking to recover most of that fee from an insolvent estate, cannot be said to be acting in the best interests of the estate’s creditors.

Even when an IP has ceased to act and the company in question has been dissolved, ICAEW is still able to investigate complaints and, as demonstrated in this case, the IP could be required to repay an element of their fees. In addition, even if fees have been properly approved by creditors and there have been no external complaints, that would not prevent ICAEWvfrom investigating whether fees are reasonable.

What does the Insolvency Act say?

The introduction of the Regulatory Objectives in 2015 in section 391C(3) of the Insolvency Act require recognised professional bodies such as ICAEW to discharge their regulatory functions in a way that is compatible with the regulatory objectives. Two of these have relevance to the level of an IP’s fees; the requirement in section 391C(3)(b) to provide high quality services at a cost to the recipient which is fair and reasonable and that in (c) to promote the maximisation of the value of returns to creditors.

Common quality assurance review findings

Allison Broad, Senior Manager, ICAEW Quality Assurance Department explains what our reviewers look for regarding time cost-based fees and highlights some of the issues that would cause concern during a monitoring visit.

It won’t come as any surprise to hear that ICAEW’s Quality Assurance Department looks at IP fees during monitoring reviews. That doesn’t just mean whether fees have been properly authorised and correctly calculated, but also extends to the amount sought in an estimate and the fees that are drawn.

Quality assurance monitoring process

Where we have concerns about an IP’s fees, we will first raise that in our written queries and ask for comments and additional information. If we still have concerns, the next stage is for us to report the issue to ICAEW’s Insolvency Licensing Committee. The IP has a further opportunity to make additional comments at that stage. If the committee believes that the matter requires further review (as in the case described above) it will refer the matter to ICAEW’s Conduct Department. The Conduct team will have the opportunity to investigate the position in much more detail than we have time to do during a monitoring visit.

Some of the issues that cause us concern are set out below, and we would encourage ICAEW-licensed insolvency practitioners to take note of these and check they aren’t making any of these mistakes.

Activities that aren’t relevant to a case

We question time included in a fee estimate for areas of work that aren’t applicable to the case. For example, including time in a fee estimate for:

  • trading, when the business had already ceased trading;
  • agreeing creditor claims, when the IP has already said that there’s no prospect of a dividend; or
  • debt collection work, where the company doesn’t have any debts.

Similarly, we would question time entries allocated to activities that don’t appear to be relevant to a case, or time entries that relate to staff who don’t appear to have been involved in the case.

As the case above highlights, narrative is important. When looking at time records, our reviewers can find it difficult to understand the work that has been undertaken if there’s limited narrative. As the case above highlights, narrative is important. When looking at time records, our reviewers can find it difficult to understand the work that has been undertaken if there’s limited narrative.

Some firms have very detailed time codes with a vast array of sub-codes beneath them, but even then some narrative is useful to clarify the work undertaken. This is particularly true if large periods of time are allocated to certain tasks and we can’t see evidence of that work. We don’t need to see war and peace – but we do need enough to understand what the time relates to. That detail can be useful for IPs as well, in terms of managing staff, and also if fees are challenged.

Level of staff

Again, as illustrated in the case above, concerns also arise where a senior member of staff (or the IP) is undertaking work seemingly more suited to someone more junior. Where that’s necessary, for example if more junior staff aren’t available, we would expect the IP to discount their charge out rate so that the rate being charged reflects the underlying task. This is also relevant to sole IPs who don’t have junior staff. In this case we expect to see the work more suited to junior staff being charged at a lower rate.

We’d also expect IPs to consider the recoverability of costs incurred where cases are being handed over from one team member to another. Is it right for the creditors to bear the cost of new members of staff reviewing the files to get up to speed with the case? We would say not.

Insolvency practitioners are in a privileged position to draw their fees from funds under their control, and it’s critical that this isn’t abused.

2023 Restructuring and Insolvency Community Compliance update webinar

Insolvency compliance update: estimating fees

Is your time recording system accurate?

Find out more about ICAEW’s disciplinary process

Add Verified CPD Activity

case study on financial regulation

Introducing AddCPD, a new way to record your CPD activities!

Add this page to your cpd activity, step 1 of 3, download recorded, download not recorded.

Please download the related document if you wish to add this activity to your record

Step 2 of 3

Add activity to my record, step 3 of 3, activity added, an error has occurred please try again.

Read out this code to the operator.

Asking the better questions that unlock new answers to the working world's most complex issues.

Trending topics

AI insights

EY Center for Board Matters

EY podcasts

EY webcasts

Operations leaders

Technology leaders

EY helps clients create long-term value for all stakeholders. Enabled by data and technology, our services and solutions provide trust through assurance and help clients transform, grow and operate.

EY.ai - A unifying platform

Strategy, transaction and transformation consulting

Technology transformation

Tax function operations

Climate change and sustainability services

EY Ecosystems

EY Nexus: business transformation platform

Discover how EY insights and services are helping to reframe the future of your industry.

Case studies

How Mojo Fertility is helping more men conceive

26-Sep-2023 Lisa Lindström

Strategy and Transactions

How a cosmetics giant’s transformation strategy is unlocking value

13-Sep-2023 Nobuko Kobayashi

How a global biopharma became a leader in ethical AI

15-Aug-2023 Catriona Campbell

We bring together extraordinary people, like you, to build a better working world.

Experienced professionals

EY-Parthenon careers

Student and entry level programs

Talent community

At EY, our purpose is building a better working world. The insights and services we provide help to create long-term value for clients, people and society, and to build trust in the capital markets.

Press release

Extreme E and EY publish Season 3 report, recording 8.2% carbon footprint reduction as female-male performance gap continues to narrow

09-Apr-2024 Michael Curtis

EY announces acceleration of client AI Business Model adoption with NVIDIA AI

20-Mar-2024 Barbara Dimajo

EY announces launch of artificial intelligence platform EY.ai following US$1.4b investment

13-Sep-2023 Rachel Lloyd

No results have been found

 alt=

Recent Searches

case study on financial regulation

How do you steady the course of your IPO journey in a changing landscape?

EY Global IPO Trends Q1 2024 provides insights, facts and figures on the IPO market and implications for companies planning to go public. Learn more.

case study on financial regulation

How can the moments that threaten your transformation define its success?

Leaders that put humans at the center to navigate turning points are 12 times more likely to significantly improve transformation performance. Learn More.

case study on financial regulation

Artificial Intelligence

EY.ai - a unifying platform

Select your location

close expand_more

What EU Deforestation Regulation compliance readiness looks like

In this webcast, panelists discuss effective compliance and reporting readiness actions for EUDR, case studies and broader strategic considerations.

Related topics

With the EU Deforestation Regulation (EUDR), the European Union (EU) aims to ensure certain products and commodities imported, traded within or exported from the EU have not led to deforestation or forest degradation, and have been produced in compliance with the legislation of the country of origin.

As of 30 December 2024, impacted businesses are required to provide due diligence statements verifying the ‘deforestation-free’ and legality status of commodities and products in scope. Products in scope are: cattle, beef and leather, cocoa beans, cocoa shells, cocoa mass, cocoa butter and chocolate; coffee, beans, husks; palm oil, nuts and seeds; rubber and rubber products; soybeans, bean flour and bean oil; wood, furniture, cellulose and paper (full list can be found in Annex I of the regulation).

Topics discussed include:

  • EUDR overview, data requirements, reporting obligations and timeline
  • Immediate steps for impacted businesses to take considering traceability challenges
  • Practical case studies on how businesses are preparing for EUDR
  • Strategic and operational considerations in the broader ESG regulatory context

A second webcast covered potential supply chain challenges and opportunities related to EUDR. Watch the replay here.

case study on financial regulation

Michelle T. Davies

EY Global Sustainability Legal Services Leader; Partner, Law, Ernst & Young LLP

case study on financial regulation

Linn Anker-Sørensen

EY Global Sustainable Finance Law and Regulation Leader

ondemand_video Webcast

schedule Time

your local time

case study on financial regulation

  • Connect with us
  • Our locations
  • Legal and privacy
  • Open Facebook profile
  • Open X profile
  • Open LinkedIn profile
  • Open Youtube profile

EY refers to the global organization, and may refer to one or more, of the member firms of Ernst & Young Global Limited, each of which is a separate legal entity. Ernst & Young Global Limited, a UK company limited by guarantee, does not provide services to clients.

IMAGES

  1. Case Study In Financial Management With Solution

    case study on financial regulation

  2. Case Assignment Financial Report

    case study on financial regulation

  3. (PDF) Case Study of Financial Planning and Design in Power Assets

    case study on financial regulation

  4. Case Study In Financial Management With Solution

    case study on financial regulation

  5. Your Guide to Understanding Financial Regulation

    case study on financial regulation

  6. How To Do A Financial Analysis Case Study

    case study on financial regulation

VIDEO

  1. Case Study Financial Services

  2. Credit Risk

  3. Why is Investment Bank Fascinating ?

  4. REGISTER FOR ICAN EXEMPTION! #studytips #ICAN #icanexams

  5. Financial Reporting and Forecasting Transformation at Odido (Formally T-Mobile)

  6. Financial Process Transformation at OTC Industrial Technologies

COMMENTS

  1. PDF Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and

    B. Case Study #2: Independent Boards For Mutual Funds C. Case Study #3: Heightened Capital Requirements For Banks D. Case Study #4: The Volcker Rule E. "Gold-Standard" Examples of CBA/FR 1. The SEC's Cross-Border Swaps Rules 2. The FSA's Mortgage Market Reforms F. Summary of Case Studies IV. WHAT ARE THE IMPLICATIONS OF THESE CASE STUDIES?

  2. Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and

    The third case study is of bank capital rule reforms adopted in the wake of the 2008 to 2009 financial crisis. Among other things, the case study illustrates how difficult it is to quantify one of the core benefits of a great number—perhaps the majority—of financial regulations: reductions in systemic risk.

  3. Subject

    The Case Study Teaching Method; Harvard Law Case Studies A-Z; Free Materials; Blog; Shop By Category; Harvard Law Case Studies A-Z; Free Materials; Program; Role Play; Workshop-Based Case Study; Discussion-Based Case Study; DVD; Subject; Sabrineh Ardalan; Sharon Block; Robert Bordone; Emily M. Broad Leib; Chad Carr; Robert Clark; John Coates ...

  4. 3. Case 2. Digitalisation in finance: regulatory challenges and

    The case study also highlights that the fast-paced, cross-border implications of Fintech innovations warrant strengthening international regulatory co-operation and further developing anticipatory approaches to regulation. ... This may include discussions on how the Danish FSA can support the fintech environment within the scope of the ...

  5. The Case for Financial Regulation

    Invest in the future of investing. The Case for Financial Regulation. By Marissa Li. What's Ahead: Learn about the history of financial regulation in the United States and read about Marissa's argument that we now need greater financial regulation. From Glass-Steagall to Dodd-Frank, the United States has come a long way in terms of ...

  6. Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and

    The 2010 Dodd-Frank Act mandated over 200 new rules, bringing renewed attention to the use of cost-benefit analysis (CBA) in financial regulation. CBA proponents and industry advocates have criticized the independent financial regulatory agencies for failing to base the new rules on CBA, and many have sought to mandate judicial review of quantified CBA (examples […]

  7. Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and ...

    COST-BENEFIT ANALYSIS OF FINANCIAL REGULATION INTRODUCTION A movement is afoot to impose cost-benefit analysis (CBA) on financial regulation (CBĄ/FR).1 The housing and financial crises of 2008 led to the Dodd-Frank Act,2 which restructured the financial regulatory agencies, man-dated more than 200 new rules, and required changes to many older ...

  8. Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and

    John C. Coates, Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and Implications, 124 Yale L. J. 882 (2015). ... Detailed case studies of six rules—(1) disclosure rules under Sarbanes-Oxley section 404; (2) the SEC's mutual fund governance reforms; (3) Basel III's heightened capital requirements for banks; (4) the Volcker Rule ...

  9. Foundations of Financial Regulation

    This chapter introduces one of the core themes of this study: financial regulation. It not only explores each theme individually but also delves into the relationship between them. In order to explore the phenomenon of fintech, it also provides a basic introduction to the financial market and how financial regulation and financial innovation as ...

  10. Financial Regulation Case Study: Consumer Financial Protection Bureau

    financial regulation, cfpb, consumer, financial, protection, bureau, inancial Regulation Case Study: Consumer Financial Protection Bureau | HLS Case Studies Toggle menu 617-496-1316

  11. Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and ...

    Coates, John C., Cost-Benefit Analysis of Financial Regulation: Case Studies and Implications (January 6, 2014). European Corporate Governance Institute (ECGI) - Law Working Paper No. 234/2014, Harvard Public Law Working Paper No. 14-05, ...

  12. Transparency and accountability influences of regulation on risk

    This qualitative in-depth case study explores the influence of financial regulation on risk control within Banque de Montagne, a large listed bank in Sweden. Specifically, the purpose of this paper is to investigate the impact of the European Banking Authority´s Guidelines on Internal Governance (GL 44), through Swedish Financial Regulation FFFS 2014:1, on the bank's risk organization along ...

  13. PDF Financial Regulation Case Study

    Financial Regulation Case Study Bank Secrecy Act, Anti-Money Laundering Law Compliance & Blockchain Technology MEMORANDUM* TO: Junior FinCEN Lawyer RE: Recommendations Regarding Adopting Blockchain Technology for BSA/AML Compliance DATE: November 2016 You are a junior attorney at the United States Department of the Treasury Financial Crimes

  14. Digital Transformation of Financial Regulators and the Emergence of

    This article provides a case study of the use of SupTech by the U.K. Financial Conduct Authority (FCA). Through 16 qualitative interviews with senior colleagues at the FCA and other regulators, this study focuses on how the field of SupTech has emerged and how the FCA developed its SupTech tool (BLENDER) to monitor market abuse in financial ...

  15. Full article: Financial fraud, scandals, and regulation: A conceptual

    1. A conceptual framework for the historical study of fraud and scandals. The classic framework for studying fraud is the so-called 'fraud triangle', consisting of the incentive (or pressure) to commit fraud, the opportunity for fraud, and its rationalisation by perpetrators (for a brief explanation, see Hollow, Citation 2015).In their synthesis, Trompeter et al. (2013) adopt an expanded ...

  16. 1. Overview

    Developing governance frameworks to enable the development of agile and future-proof regulation such as outcome-based regulations (e.g. data-driven regulation and rules as code (Mohun and Roberts, 2020[22]), fixed-term regulatory exemptions (e.g. regulatory sandboxes), co-regulation and non-regulatory approaches such as voluntary codes or ...

  17. Financial Inclusion and Virtual Bank in the Era of ...

    Financial regulation; Financial inclusion; Virtual banking; Bank digitization; Digitalization; JEL Classification. E58; 1 Introduction. ... This case study leads to a few recommendations for the regulators to amend existing guidelines to address technological feature of the virtual bank, review and accommodate the differences in the bank ...

  18. PDF CASE STUDY No 1

    CASE STUDY No 1 . Domain 4: Financial security and dignified work: Inequality in the capability to achieve financial independence and security, enjoy dignified and fair work, and recognition of unpaid work and care . Main Driver Category 4.11: Lack of regulation of financial sector; unequal access to banking services,

  19. Cashing Out a Special Relationship?: Trends Toward Reconciliation

    Like an optical illusion or an Escher drawing, the relationship between financial regulation and administrative law is intricate and prone to reflect one's perspective. 1 From a distance, the fields may appear entirely in sync, even derivative. Financial regulation — legal structures governing markets, institutions, and actors — is formally bound by the procedural constraints of ...

  20. The FinTech Revolution and Financial Regulation: The Case of Online

    Online supply-chain financing has been a relatively novel funding channel for suppliers as small- and medium-sized enterprises ("SMEs") to obtain loans in that the revolution of financial technology ("FinTech") transforms traditional supply-chain financing, which used to be administered only by official banks, to an online model also used by electronic commerce platforms ("e-commerce ...

  21. Disciplinary case study: insolvency practitioner fees

    The IP accepted that fees for this area of work had been disproportionately weighted towards partner time and that some of the time costs incurred, and recovered, were unreasonable and excessive. The IP received a severe reprimand, a financial penalty of £20,000 and was required to pay costs of £25,365. The IP also agreed to repay £100,000 ...

  22. How to prepare for EU Deforestation Regulation

    With the EU Deforestation Regulation (EUDR), the European Union (EU) aims to ensure certain products and commodities imported, traded within or exported from the EU have not led to deforestation or forest degradation, and have been produced in compliance with the legislation of the country of origin. As of 30 December 2024, impacted businesses ...

  23. Section 19:31-11.9

    Section 19:31-11.9 - Evaluation process for financial assistance (a) When all of the required information is received, the Authority shall perform its own credit evaluation based on the following, as applicable: 1. Visitation to the applicant's place of business; 2. An analysis of historic and projected financial statements and a comparison to industry peers; 3.

  24. La. Admin. Code tit. 28 § V-131

    Section V-131 - Rules of Order A. When not in conflict with any of the provisions of these bylaws, Roberts' Rules of Order shall constitute the rules of parliamentary procedure applicable to all meetings of the advisory council. La. Admin. Code tit. 28, § V-131. Promulgated by the Tuition Trust Authority, Office of Student Financial Assistance, LR 50492 (4/1/2024).

  25. La. Admin. Code tit. 28 § V-239

    Section V-239 - Minutes. A. At a minimum, the minutes of the advisory board shall record official motions or recommendations that are voted on by the advisory board. The minutes may contain a summary of reports and pertinent discussion of issues. Each recommendation shall be reduced to writing and presented to the advisory board before it is ...

  26. La. Admin. Code tit. 28 § V-139

    Code tit. 28 § V-139. A. At a minimum, the minutes of the advisory council shall record official motions or recommendations that are voted on by the advisory council. The minutes may contain a summary of reports and pertinent discussion of issues. Each recommendation shall be reduced to writing and presented to the advisory council before it ...